June 2020
ADVICE, MONEY, RESULTS
Rethinking International Support for
Managing Public Finance
Report by an International Working Group
Advice, Money, Results
Rethinking International Support for
Managing Public Finance
Report by an International Working Group
New York University
Robert F. Wagner Graduate School of Public Service
June 2020
CONTENTS
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS ...........................................................................................................................i
ABBREVIATIONS ................................................................................................................................... iii
ABSTRACT ................................................................................................................................................iv
1. INTRODUCTION: SETTING THE AGENDA ...................................................................................1
Scope of inquiry ............................................................................................................................................1
The state of PFM in 2019 ..............................................................................................................................2
Four problems for the PFM community .......................................................................................................2
Guiding framework: an “open” model of PFM ...........................................................................................6
Developing some responses ..........................................................................................................................7
Organization of the report ............................................................................................................................8
2. MANAGING PUBLIC FINANCE: A REAPPRAISAL ....................................................................10
Managing public nance and PFM: meaning and denitions ....................................................................10
Public nancial management in context ..................................................................................................... 11
PFM as a “professional discipline” and its conventions ...........................................................................12
Guiding objectives of PFM and their evolution ..........................................................................................19
Moving on from here ...................................................................................................................................26
3. BUILDING ON THE STRENGTHS OF THE “CLOSED” PFM MODEL .................................... 27
Faster learning about external support for PFM .......................................................................................27
Contestation and choice in PFM advice .....................................................................................................32
Moving on from here ...................................................................................................................................39
4. RETHINKING MANAGING PUBLIC FINANCE IN AN “OPEN” SYSTEM .............................40
Linking PFM to service delivery and development results .........................................................................40
Harnessing PFM for policy change ............................................................................................................47
Moving on from here ...................................................................................................................................54
5. PUTTING IDEAS INTO PRACTICE ................................................................................................56
An agenda for change: some proposals for the PFM discipline ................................................................. 56
Building a persuasive case for change: some initial ideas .........................................................................57
Moving on from here ...................................................................................................................................59
CHAPTER REFERENCES .....................................................................................................................60
ANNEXES .................................................................................................................................................75
ENDNOTES.............................................................................................................................................118
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
ANNEXES, TABLES, AND FIGURES
Annex A: Key concepts and terms used in the report .................................................................................75
Annex B: A framework for public policy—government policy choices, government actions,
and development results ..............................................................................................................................82
Annex C: Public nancial management reforms in context .......................................................................90
Annex D: PFM focus within World Bank sector activities .........................................................................93
Annex E: The quality of data on development nancing for PFM .............................................................95
Annex F: Mapping of PFM assessment frameworks ..................................................................................97
Annex G: Relating the institutional and economic perspectives on PFM—a thought experiment ..........101
Annex H: A partial summary of PFM research .........................................................................................105
Annex I: The elusive hope of incorporating context.................................................................................109
Annex J: Evolution in theories of externally supported change in the public sector ................................ 112
Annex K: Putting external contestation of policy ideas into practice ....................................................... 115
Table 1: Proposals for a new direction for managing public nance ............................................................ 7
Table 2: Refreshing the PFM objectives – proposals for discussion ..........................................................24
Table 3: The basis for recommending specic PFM conventions ..............................................................45
Table 4: A recap on the problems and proposals ......................................................................................... 57
Table 5: Terms of art used in the report ......................................................................................................76
Table 6: Government actions for public services range from direct provision to regulation......................88
Table 7: Recent public sector reforms.........................................................................................................90
Table 8: Mapping of PFM assessment tools ...............................................................................................97
Table 9: Capabilities of an effective PFM system and their relationship to public nance objectives ....103
Table 10: A partial summary of key research ............................................................................................ 105
Table 11: Adaptive Management, Doing Development Differently, and Thinking and Working
Politically vs. Berg’s ideas from the early 1990s ......................................................................................110
Table 12: Stylized theories of growth and of externally supported change in public management .........112
Figure 1: “Opening up” perspectives on means and ends in managing public nance ................................6
Figure 2: External funding for PFM, comparison of ve-year totals (US$ billions) ..................................14
Figure 3: Internal and external funding by PFM reform area for a basket of countries (US$ billions) .....14
Figure 4: Links and interactions between the dimensions of public policy ................................................83
Figure 5: Ngram plot of references in literature published in English containing the terms “service
delivery” and “development assistance” .....................................................................................................85
Figure 6: Proportion of activities with a signicant PFM component in the Health, Nutrition, and
Population Global Practice .........................................................................................................................93
Figure 7: Proportion of activities with a signicant PFM component in the Education
Global Practice ............................................................................................................................................94
Figure 8: Proportion of activities with a signicant PFM component in the Governance
Global Practice ............................................................................................................................................94
Figure 9: Causal chains and attributions to be considered ........................................................................105
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
i
An International Working Group on Managing
Public Finance, operating with guidance from
an Advisory Group of eminent persons, was
convened between January 2018 and August 2019
to investigate and debate the effectiveness of the
development assistance architecture in supporting
public nancial management and to consider
future directions for international support. This
report is the result of that work.
The initiative was hosted by the Robert F.
Wagner Graduate School of Public Service at
New York University and was funded through a
research grant from the Bill and Melinda Gates
Foundation. The views expressed in the report do
not necessarily reect those of either organization.
The usual disclaimers all apply.
Members of the Working Group include Edward
Hedger, Roger Koppl, Florence Kuteesa, Nick
Manning, Barbara Nunberg, Jana Orac (Project
Manager), Allen Schick, Paul Smoke (Project
Director), and Duvvuri Subbarao. Contributions
by Marco Cangiano, who served as a member
of the Working Group until 2018, are gratefully
acknowledged.
Members of the Advisory Group include Vicente
Fretes Cibils (Inter-American Development
Bank, or IADB), Neil Cole (Collaborative Africa
Budget Reform Initiative, or CABRI), Salam
Fayyad (Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton
University), Keith Hansen (World Bank), Homi
Kharas (Brookings Institution), Rathin Roy
(National Institute of Public Finance and Policy,
India), Antoinette Sayeh (Center for Global
Development), Seth Terkper (PFM-Tax Africa
Network), and Debbie Wetzel (World Bank).
Particular thanks are due to Thomas
Kalogeropoulos, Suley Ouattara, and Jocelyne
Uwayo, who provided valuable research
assistance, and to Vishal Gujadhur and Chisom
Okechukwu of the Gates Foundation for their
strategic guidance. The idea for the Working
Group originated from Philipp Krause at the
Gates Foundation, whose advice and feedback
throughout the work is gratefully acknowledged.
Amanda Green edited the report with meticulous
care.
The Working Group consulted a large number
of experts in public nance and development
cooperation, who gave generously of their time,
ideas, and advice. Those individuals include Awo
Ablo, Mike Ablowich, Tera Allas, Richard Allen,
Jean-François Almanza, Katherine Baer, Owen
Barder, Erik Berglof, Jon Blondal, Jurgen Blum,
David Bontempo, Martin Bowen, Chiara Bronchi,
Jim Brumby, Kalipso Chalkidou, Chris Chalmers,
Matt Davies, Cem Dener, Paolo de Renzio, Shanta
Devarajan, Bill Dorotinsky, Riccardo Ercoli,
Thomas Feige, Manal Fouad, Adrian Fozzard,
Verena Fritz, Erica Gerretsen, Sanjeev Gupta,
Sierd Hadley, Tobias Haque, Dan Honig, Alan
Hudson, Richard Hughes, Sachiko Imoto, Phil
Keefer, Stuti Khemani, Maia King, Rajesh Kishan,
Shivin Kohli, Jens Kristensen, Vincent Larrouze,
Edwin Lau, Andrew Lawson, Mary McCarthy,
Larry McDonald, Mark Miller, Rob Mills, Ian
Mitchell, Hakon Mundal, Piroska Nagy-Mohacsi,
Peter Nicholas, Aimée Nichols, Jason Orlando,
Steve Pierce, Carlos Pimenta, Mark Plant, Vivek
Ramkumar, Carolina Renteria, Andrew Rogerson,
Jacek Rostowski, Carlos Santiso, Bill Savedoff,
Salvatore Schiavo-Campo, Rosmarie Schlup,
Robert Schoellhammer, Renaud Seligmann, Bing
Xun Seng, Rebecca Simson, Gregory Smith,
Nicola Smithers, Franziska Spoerri, Stephanie
Sweet, Rob Taliercio, Teresa Ter-Minassian,
Chris Tinning, Rachel Turner, Sanjay Vani, Clay
Wescott, Alan Whitworth, Ellen Wichmann, and
Jennifer Widner.
Important insights were provided by nance
ministry ofcials from Ghana, Lesotho, Liberia,
and Nigeria at a CABRI workshop in Pretoria in
May 2018. Valuable feedback on draft versions
was obtained from presentations made to the
Public Expenditure and Financial Accountability
(PEFA) Steering Committee in June and December
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
ii
2018, and at a symposium organized by New
York University, Princeton University, and the
Overseas Development Institute (ODI) in May
2019 in Washington, D.C.
The Working Group drew from a signicant body
of published research. The bibliographies for each
chapter are not exhaustive, but they do highlight
the most signicant references used as part of this
work.
The Working Group welcomes reactions to this
report. Please direct any questions or comments to
the principal authors:
Nick Manning ([email protected])
Edward Hedger ([email protected])
Allen Schick ([email protected])
Please copy the director of the overall initiative,
Paul Smoke ([email protected]).
Acknowledgments
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
iii
ABBREVIATIONS
ADB Asian Development Bank
BMZ FederalMinistryofEconomicCooperaonandDevelopment(Germany)
CABRI CollaboraveAfricaBudgetReformIniave
CPIA CountryPolicyandInstuonalAssessment
DAC DevelopmentAssistanceCommiee(OECD)
Danida DanishInternaonalDevelopmentAgency
DeMPA DebtManagementPerformanceAssessment
DFAT DepartmentforForeignAairsandTrade(Australia)
DFID DepartmentforInternaonalDevelopment(UnitedKingdom)
EC EuropeanCommission
EU EuropeanUnion
FMIS FinancialManagementInformaonSystem
G20 GroupofTwenty
GDP GrossDomescProduct
GIZ GesellschafürInternaonaleZusammenarbeit(GermanSocietyfor
InternaonalCooperaon)
IADB Inter-American Development Bank
IEG IndependentEvaluaonGroup
IFI InternaonalFinancialInstuon
ILO InternaonalLabourOrganizaon
IMF InternaonalMonetaryFund
IPSAS InternaonalPublicSectorAccounngStandards
IT InformaonTechnology
MDB MullateralDevelopmentBank
MTEF Medium-TermExpenditureFramework
NGO Non-governmentalOrganizaon
NYU NewYorkUniversity
ODA OcialDevelopmentAssistance
ODI OverseasDevelopmentInstute
OECD OrganisaonforEconomicCo-operaonandDevelopment
OOF OtherOcialFlows
PEFA PublicExpenditureandFinancialAccountabilityprogram
PEMNA PublicExpenditureManagementNetworkinAsia
PEMPAL PublicExpenditureManagementPeer-AssistedLearningnetwork
PFM PublicFinancialManagement
PIMA PublicInvestmentManagementAssessment
SARA Semi-AutonomousRevenueAuthority
SDGs SustainableDevelopmentGoals
SNA SystemofNaonalAccounts
TADAT TaxAdministraonDiagnoscAssessmentTool
TOSSD TotalOcialSupportforSustainableDevelopment
UNDESA UnitedNaonsDepartmentofEconomicandSocialAairs
UNDP UnitedNaonsDevelopmentProgramme
UK UnitedKingdom
US UnitedStates
USAID UnitedStatesAgencyforInternaonalDevelopment
iv
The current paradigm of public nancial
management (PFM) in international development
has proved remarkably successful as the basis for a
common approach, supported by a wide consensus
among practitioners, advisers, and researchers.
That approach emphasizes conformity with a set
of processes and conventions aimed at achieving
a standard trinity of PFM objectives: scal
discipline, allocative efciency, and operational
efciency. The approach is powerful and has
provided practical means for those seeking to
strengthen the institutional foundations of PFM.
Improvements are still needed, however, to make
external interventions on PFM more effective and
to connect PFM more strongly to all levels of
public policy.
Further enhancing the effectiveness of external
interventions within the current paradigm will
require better sharing of evidence and knowledge
about intervention design. This could arguably
be facilitated by a stronger role for debate and
government choice among external advice options.
This is a demanding technical agenda.
Strengthening links between institutional
arrangements for public nancial management
and country-specic public policy raises more
challenging conceptual questions, however. From
a policy perspective, the PFM paradigm is at
the limits of relevance and utility in its current,
inwardly focused form. It is constrained in its
capacity to engage with real-world choices and
dilemmas.
The current approach treats PFM as a “closed”
system, in which the PFM processes and
conventions that drive operational performance
are considered to be unchanging ends in and of
themselves. Viewing PFM instead as an “open”
system that interacts more uently with all aspects
of public policy—namely, government policy
choices, government actions (especially service
delivery), and development results—offers the
potential for developing a new generation of
approaches to managing public nance. This
broader perspective would better reect the
complex realities of context and the unavoidable
nature of trade-offs in policy objectives.
This “open” conception of PFM, proposed by
the International Working Group on Managing
Public Finance, is distinguished by a willingness
to revise and expand the guiding objectives for
managing public nance and to reappraise the
conventions that drive the form and content of
external technical advice in this area. It sees
conventions about the operational performance
of PFM processes as useful benchmarks, without
con-sidering them to be set in stone or remaining
blind to their purpose of informing and delivering
wider public policy outcomes.
The report motivates and frames this ambitious
and challenging agenda. It identies problems
with current approaches to external assistance in
PFM and offers specic proposals on how to move
toward a new, more “open” model of managing
public nance that is t for the 2020s and a post-
COVID world grappling with climate change.
ABSTRACT
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
1
Scope of inquiry
Advice, money, and results are central concerns
in international support for managing public
nance. Technical advice is the mainstay of
external assistance for strengthening scal
institutions. Effective use of development nance
and domestic resources is a priority for donors
and governments alike. Development results are
ultimately the raison d’être of managing public
nance. As a raft of recent reviews, evaluations,
and policy initiatives indicates, these matters are
persistent preoccupations for the international
community when considering lower-income
countries, and there is strong demand for ideas,
innovation, and progress (Coady & Murgasova,
2019; IMF, 2018a, 2019; IEG, 2018; Lagarde,
2019; Shanmugaratnam et al., 2018; World Bank,
2019b). This report speaks directly to the question
of how the self-described domain of public
nancial management (PFM) can contribute more,
and more quickly, to development results.
The report argues that now is the right time to
review and re-evaluate the scope, objectives,
and results of the PFM agenda and the
development assistance that supports it. It sets
out some of the frontier challenges confronting
PFM and considers how the PFM community
should respond. In doing so, it poses several
questions. First, long-standing PFM objectives
have shaped the design of external technical
advice based on an increasingly standardized set
of PFM processes and conventions. To the extent
that these conventions reect a widely accepted set
of institutional practices, how can external support
for reforms be made more effective? Second,
greater choice by client governments is often
suggested as a way to drive up effectiveness. How
could greater contestation of ideas and intervention
approaches be deployed to support institutional
reforms? Third, a strong PFM system is assumed
to contribute to service delivery and sector
outcomes. What is actually known about those
connections and the ways in which PFM makes a
difference for development results? Fourth, major
policy concerns such as tackling climate change
and boosting infrastructure development will
require massive reprioritization in budget policies.
Are the standard PFM processes and conventions
up to the task? What changes are needed? What
can PFM do to support better analysis of the trade-
offs in policy objectives posed by socioeconomic
concerns such as inequality, which are regaining
political salience but are crowded out by other
scal objectives?
The analysis and recommendations presented
here draw on 18 months of in-depth and wide-
ranging deliberations by an International
Working Group on Managing Public Finance.
The questions examined by the Working Group are
at the forefront of debates among policy makers,
practitioners, and academics concerned with
international support to PFM. They intentionally
push at the boundaries of what has conventionally
been considered the terrain of PFM and its primary
areas of concern. For the purposes of this report,
PFM is treated in broad terms as a set of processes
that connect public resources with public policy
while serving the wider nancial purposes of
accounting and accountability. Although it is a
highly technical topic, discussion of PFM is often
accompanied by terms that are generalized and
ambiguous rather than specic and consistent. To
avoid confusion, this report employs a standard
lexicon of relevant “terms of art,” which is set out,
with examples, in Annex A.
1. INTRODUCTION: SETTING THE AGENDA
2
The state of PFM in 2019
The scope and objectives of PFM are not
timeless; they can and should be reviewed,
refreshed, and expanded to reect the full
range of contemporary policy concerns and
goals. Fiscal discipline, allocative efciency,
and operational efciency have been adopted
widely by the international PFM community
as the explicit aims of the PFM system—the
“holy trinity” of standard PFM objectives. These
objectives have had a powerful impact on the
content of technical advice to governments over
the past two decades. They have, however, created
a bias toward short-term measures to ensure scal
discipline. More generally, the broad consensus
around these proximate and technical objectives
has masked an underlying normative and value-
based conict about the aims of government
policy. Obscuring the inherent tensions among
scal objectives and broader socioeconomic
outcomes does not remove those tensions. They
are always present, and it is a fundamental task
of democratic politics to try to mitigate or resolve
them. Refreshing and expanding the objectives
of PFM—as proposed in this report—would play
a part in helping to rebalance policy priorities in
a way that allows these normative conicts to
surface and be resolved through consultative and
political processes.
International support for PFM has assumed a
distinctively strong place in development, with
its own professional discipline and a strong set
of conventions about desirable practices. While
it is challenging to impose a single framework on
the analysis of public nance writ large, PFM has
emerged as a more distinct and tractable domain
within this larger and conceptually more uncertain
context. The term leaned strongly toward the
management of general government expenditures
in the 1990s, but most standard denitions of
PFM have broadened since then to encompass
the revenue side of the budget, the wider public
sector, and the relationship to scal policy.
PFM has risen rapidly in importance within
development assistance overall, and a distinct
PFM “discipline” has emerged. The associated
disciplinary approach encompasses a set of
strong normative conventions about what PFM
institutional arrangements should be, built on the
premise that conformity with these conventions is
necessary, if not sufcient, to achieve the trinity
of objectives. The discipline has more recently
evolved to recognize the signicance of problem-
based and adaptive approaches, which are offering
increasingly nuanced advice about sequencing the
standard PFM objectives and how conformity with
PFM conventions might realistically be achieved.
Four problems for the PFM
community
The central argument of the Working Group
is that the paradigm of PFM in international
development has become too inwardly focused
and needs to reconnect with broader policies
and results. Although the current disciplinary
approach has been of considerable value and still
has much to offer in accelerating improvements
in PFM, further progress could be made through
better sharing of evidence and knowledge about
intervention approaches and by introducing a
stronger role for debate and government choice
over external advice options. This approach would
strengthen PFM within the terms of its current
framing, but is insufcient on its own. The current
overall framework for PFM is limited and self-
referential. It assumes a “closed” system in which
PFM processes and conventions are considered to
be ends in themselves, independent of variations
in policy objectives. While these conventions
may provide useful guideposts, they are a weak
alternative to a more “open” model, in which the
inuences of PFM on government policy choices,
government actions (especially service delivery),
and development results are the central focus
(see Annex A for denition of specic terms,
and Annex B for an elaboration of the integrated
public policy framework used in this report).
Refreshing and expanding the objectives of
PFM to bring in these wider agendas is a starting
Chapter 1. Introduction:
Setting the Agenda
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
3
point in highlighting the complex trade-offs
involved and thus strengthening the role of PFM
in helping policy makers to address real-world
priorities, choices, and decisions. Treating PFM
as an “open” system that interacts uently with
the policy domain would bring the development
sector into line with how managing public nance
is viewed in emerging and advanced economies
(Schick, 2019).
Improving support for strengthening PFM on
its own terms and restoring the inuence of
PFM on wider development outcomes are the
twin concerns of this report. While the ambition
of the Working Group is to motivate a change
in the PFM paradigm and in the mindset of the
PFM community, it is clear that such an evolution
may take time. In the meantime, there remains an
immediate opportunity to improve the effective-
ness of technical advice on current terms. The
challenges addressed by this report reect this
two-track approach, focusing rst on how to
build on the current “closed” PFM system and
then contemplating the shift to an “open” model
of PFM.
Rethinking international support for managing
public nance embodies a vast agenda, but some
clear and strong contentions have emerged
about a set of top-order issues. Drawing on
extensive consultations with practitioners,
academics, and policy makers engaged in PFM
across a wide spectrum of organizations, countries,
and perspectives, together with an in-depth review
of the literature and available evidence, this
report takes a focused and propositional approach
by selecting and examining four interrelated
challenges or “problems” in PFM that respond to
the key questions explored above.
Problem 1: The pace of learning
about how external assistance can
better support improvements in
PFM is too slow
Countries have made progress in strengthening
their PFM processes, but the contribution of
external support is hard to disentangle. Some
countries have shown improvements in PFM
according to assessment frameworks such as the
Public Expenditure and Financial Accountability
(PEFA) indicators, which reect the current
disciplinary conventions. The evidence is limited,
however, and the picture is mixed. Lower-income
countries have made gains from a low base, and
improvements link closely to country income, in
that countries with higher income per capita show
evidence of a stronger PFM system (de Renzio,
2009; Fritz, Verhoeven & Avenia, 2017). Countries
may be making progress, but it remains unclear
how international assistance providers can best
support those improvements. Assuming there is
no universal and unchanging approach waiting to
be revealed, the focus needs to be on a continuous
process of discovery and learning across different
contexts and requirements.
Technical advice is at the heart of external
support for PFM. It may be provided by
international organizations, donor governments,
consulting rms, non-prot organizations, or
individual advisers. Often it is funded, designed,
delivered, and evaluated by a combination of them.
Technical advice is embedded in many forms of
intervention: technical assistance missions or
projects, investment projects, nancial support
through government systems, pooled funds,
policy or structural reform conditions, and results-
based funding. These interventions are inuenced
increasingly by problem-driven and adaptive
approaches to institutional reform. Surprisingly
little is known, however, about the effectiveness
of any of these instruments and approaches.
Proposals for improving the effectiveness of
external interventions are often based more on
orthodoxy or belief than on evidence. Can the
evidence base be strengthened and mobilized so
that learning and improvement happen faster?
4
Problem 2: Development agencies’
preference for following a common
approach has reduced opportunities
to test ideas through competition
Debates about donor coordination and
the risks of competition among assistance
providers are long-standing. There is a growing
range of new sources of development nance
and technical assistance to governments (Custer,
DiLorenzo, Masaki, Sethi & Harutyunyan, 2018;
Greenhill, Prizzon & Rogerson, 2013; Hudson
Institute, 2016; Schmaljohann & Prizzon, 2015).
Despite renewed efforts and initiatives to improve
donor coordination and agree on common rules
and standards (Shanmugaratnam et al., 2018),
effective coordination remains hard to achieve
(Annen & Moers, 2012; Bourguignon & Platteau,
2015; Koch, Leiderer, Faust & Molenaers, 2017).
Approaches to external assistance for PFM have
sought to reduce conicting donor requirements
through a “strengthened approach” that emphasizes
government leadership and “coherent, co-ordinated
and programmatic” support by donors (OECD,
2006, p. 76). But there are critiques about the
realism and success of attempts at harmonization
and alignment (Booth, 2011). The debate about
whether and under what conditions some degree
of competition in development assistance might
be preferred to coordinated approaches—and the
desirable balance between these approaches—
remains a live one, without any clear-cut answer.
Rather than chasing a fully coordinated
approach, which seems unattainable, a more
promising avenue may be to promote greater
contestation among alternative intervention
design options and to ensure greater choice
on the part of client governments. While
competition among technical assistance providers
could in theory drive those effects, it would
carry risks and require donors to unbundle their
funding and advice or to submit themselves to
genuine competition (Barder, 2009; Easterly,
2002, 2009; Klein & Harford, 2005). That is
simply not realistic. Instead, a more modest and
possibly more powerful way forward may be to
ensure the development and rigorous assessment
of alternative intervention options proposed by a
particular organization or group of coordinating
development agencies to foster proper debate
and allow for an informed choice among these
options. This might incidentally involve a larger
number of funders or providers, but it need not do
so. It would strengthen the emphasis on ideas and
evidence about why different PFM interventions
and approaches might be expected to work. Would
the introduction of such approaches have positive
results? How could greater contestation and choice
realistically be put into effect and tested?
Problem 3: The ways in which PFM matters
for service delivery and development results
are not well understood
Despite the growing inuence of problem-
based and adaptive approaches to development
assistance, the PFM arena remains dominated
by certainty rather than experimentation.
Standardized PFM assessment frameworks are a
growth industry, and there is a propensity to look
for “scal machinery” that will be applicable across
all countries in supporting government actions and
development results (PEFA Secretariat, 2018).
The obvious risk is that one size is assumed to t
all contexts, with the underpinning assumption
that the desirable “look and feel” of PFM
processes are xed rather than remaining subject
to continuous reappraisal based on new evidence
about what matters for development results. One
way in which the PFM system can be envisaged as
more “open” is by reviewing how processes and
conventions can evolve in relation to evidence
and objectives. Could extrapolating signicantly
beyond emergent approaches in adaptation and
learning help to identify new or alternative PFM
conventions and manage the life cycle of existing
ones to better understand linkages with service
delivery and development results (Andrews, 2013;
Pritchett, Samji & Hammer, 2013)?
Experimentation is needed to learn about the
impact of different PFM conventions on the
Chapter 1. Introduction:
Setting the Agenda
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
5
efcient and effective provision of collective
goods and services. The case is easily made
that strong PFM is necessary if the public sector
is to be able to ensure effective service delivery,
whether through direct provision, commissioning,
or only government funding (see Table 6 in Annex
B for an elaboration of these alternative modes of
delivering public services). Strong procurement
systems contribute to efciency in service delivery
by ensuring better value for money in government
purchases, while effective public investment
management arrangements underpin successful
infrastructure development. Analysts have found it
distinctly harder to specify exactly which features
of PFM, when combined with other management
capabilities, are sufcient to ensure that these
functions are undertaken well. The link between
PFM and service delivery is typically described
without any specic explanations or evidence, and
it often remains generic across sectors with widely
varying characteristics (Welham, Hart, Mustapha
& Hadley, 2017, p. 18).
1
How can the ways in
which PFM matters for the provision of collective
goods and services be investigated and identied?
Problem 4: The standard objectives and
conventions of PFM are not equipped to
deal with political trade-offs or major
policy change
The pace and scale of political demands for
policy change to respond to new priorities
will test increasingly the versatility of PFM
systems. Recent announcements or proposals to
address climate change and inequality in countries
of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation
and Development (OECD) are emblematic of
some of the radical new policy directions that are
envisaged. Budgeting is inherently an incremental
process, however (Wildavsky, 1992). Efforts to
promote large-scale policy change—such as the
massive investments implied by climate change
mitigation measures (Gilmore & St. Clair, 2018)
2
or accelerating progress toward the Sustainable
Development Goals (SDGs)
3
—raise concerns that
PFM is not well-suited to facilitating signicant
reprioritization and reallocation across sectors—
especially at a time of slower economic growth.
4
PFM processes may need tailoring, or even more
fundamental adaptation, to facilitate these new
policy directions (Schick, 2013).
5
How could
PFM processes and conventions be re-envisaged
to better support or enable major policy change?
Mounting pressure on politicians to tackle
economic inequality is exposing the tensions and
trade-offs among policy objectives. The erosion
of real incomes (ILO, 2018; Rios-Avila, 2015)—
particularly in a context of declining trust in
government (Manning & Wetzel, 2010) and rising
intolerance—is making countries more vulnerable
to populism and authoritarianism (Dijkstra,
Poelman & Rodríguez-Pose, 2018; OECD, 2018).
Current policy debates across OECD countries
make an empirical case for more progressive,
comprehensive, and redistributive social agendas
(Milanovic, 2016; van der Weide & Milanovic,
2014). The tensions and trade-offs in lower-income
countries are just as acute—and may be rising
despite progress in overall poverty reduction and
favorable economic growth rates.
6
These tensions
are most apparent in the debates about how to
secure inclusive growth that addresses inequality
at the same time as overall prosperity (Lagarde,
2019). A similar tension exists in how to balance
scal discipline against the need for massive
scaling up of public investment, especially for
infrastructure. Understanding the impact of PFM
on policy objectives beyond the trinity of standard
PFM objectives exposes unavoidable policy
trade-offs. Can the PFM system be envisaged as
more “open” to debates about trade-offs and the
possibility of major policy change?
6
Guiding framework: an “open
model of PFM
A more “open” conception of PFM is proposed
as the guiding framework for rethinking
international support for managing public
nance. It would respond to knowledge and
learning from outside the PFM discipline, be
sensitive to the impact of PFM conventions
on public policy (choices, actions, and results)
(Annex B), and recognize the inevitability of
trade-offs among policy objectives. The current
archetype of PFM has been powerful and
productive, creating a culture of inquiry within the
PFM discipline about means and ends—namely
the institutional arrangements for achieving a
given set of objectives. Yet, as revealed by the four
problems identied by the Working Group, that
inquiry takes place within a constricted space. The
objectives that PFM aims to support are limited to
a narrow and standard set formulated in the mid-
1990s. Moreover, the conventions for operational
performance of PFM processes that are considered
necessary to support these objectives follow the
Figure 1: “Opening up” perspectives on means and ends in managing

Means are informed
byslowlyevolving
consensusamong
PFMpraconers
(codiedinPEFA,
DeMPA,TADAT,and
otherframeworks)
Convenonsarealso
informed by
knowledgeand
learningfromoutside
the PFM discipline
Impact of PFM
convenonsonpublic
services and
socioeconomic
outcomes
is considered
Ends are informed by a
xedsetof“desirable
budgetaryoutcomes”
(aggregatediscipline,
allocaveeciency,
operaonaleciency)
Recognionthatthere
aremulplepossible
objecvesrelangtoa
well-performingPFM
system
Possibilityoftrade-os
amongpolicy
objecvesisregarded
as inevitable and
necessary
–– Current “closed”
concepon of PFM
Addional
consideraons in
a more “open”
concepon
Means: the convenons for
operaonal performance of
PFM processes
Ends: the stated objecves
of the PFM system
Source:Authors’formulaon.
Chapter 1. Introduction:
Setting the Agenda
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
7
consensus of PFM practitioners. The eld of
PFM in development has become focused on
standardized assessments of these conventions,
with less active consideration of the ways in which
the conventions relate to policies and results.
In sum, while the current conceptual model for
PFM has underpinned considerable progress,
its limitations are now evident. It is detached
from the realities of policy making and closed to
new ideas and evidence from outside the PFM
discipline. In response, this report envisages a new
model of PFM, with a more “open” conception,
as the analytical lens for proposed future inquiry
by the PFM discipline and the wider development
assistance community (Figure 1).
Developing some responses
Based on the Working Group’s deliberations,
and in response to the identied problems,
this report sets out seven proposals for a new
direction of travel for the PFM discipline in the
2020s (Table 1). The rst set of three proposals
builds on the strengths of the existing “closed”
model of PFM. These proposals argue for more
rigorous assessment of technical advice offers,
based on evidence supporting the validity of the
intended approach and plans for the dissemination
of results, as well as for establishing practitioner
groups to share sensitive information condentially
so that they can begin to identify ways to improve
performance. In other domains these groups are
known as “data clubs” (Chapter 3). The proposals
also recommend experimenting with “managed
choice” in the provision of technical advice to
give client governments a greater say in deciding
among intervention options. A second set of four
proposals envisages PFM as an “open” system
that learns and interacts with the broader public
policy domain. These proposals argue for a review
of the current conventions embedded in standard
PFM assessment frameworks to test their validity,
and for the collection of data and evidence “at the
frontier” about which aspects of PFM operational
performance matter for service delivery. They
propose investigating how PFM conventions
can better support major policy change through
strategic reprioritization in budget policies, and
expanding the PFM toolkit to analyze trade-
offs among policy objectives and to assess
socioeconomic impact.

Building on the strengths of the current approach to PFM in development
1. Assessoersoftechnicaladviceagainststandardsfortheprovisionofinformaonandevidencejusfyingthe
approachandfortheplanneddisseminaonofdataaboutimpact
2. EstablishpraconergroupstosharesensiveperformanceinformaononPFMintervenonsonavoluntary
andcondenalbasistoidenfywaysofimprovingperformance
3.Experimentwith“managedchoice”intheprovisionoftechnicaladvice,withacoalionoffundersandclient
governmentsandthecreaonofadedicatedfundingfacility
Moving toward a more “open” system for managing public nance
4.ReviewthecurrentconvenonsembeddedinstandardPFMassessmentframeworkstotestevidenceofresults
andthedegreeofapplicabilityinadvancedeconomies
5.UsePFMassessmentframeworkstocollectdataandevidence“atthefroner”tobuildinsightsaboutwhich
aspectsofPFMoperaonalperformancemaerforservicedelivery
6.InvesgatehowPFMconvenonsandprocessescouldbeersupportnon-incrementalpolicychangethrough
strategicrepriorizaoninbudgetpolicies
7.ExpandthetoolkitofPFMtoanalyzethetrade-osamongpolicyobjecvesandtoconsiderthesocioeconomic
impactofscalandbudgetarypolicychoices
8
Building a strong case for change will be
critical in navigating adverse organizational
incentives in development agencies and making
progress on this new agenda. Through this
report, the Working Group sets out a view on the
current state of PFM and proposes an agenda for
substantive change. While the Working Group
has the benet of an independent perspective
and has been informed by extensive consultation
and engagement, not all readers will agree with
the perspective or the agenda. Even where the
arguments are convincing, vested interests may
not wish to see some changes occur. It is hoped,
however, that the ideas developed and discussed
in the report will, in and of themselves, provide
sufcient countervailing motivation to move
forward with practical actions and the piloting
of initiatives.
The public management community might
require more than technical arguments if
the agenda is to be taken seriously. There is a
strategic rationale for proactive leadership to
ensure the relevance of PFM and make external
support more effective, as a means to counter the
risk of losing ground on institutional strengthening
as a development priority. The primary risk
foreseen by the Working Group is that institutional
reform may lose its place as a prominent point
of entry for improving development results.
It could come to be seen as an expensive and
optional agenda, rather than as a precondition
for sustainable outcomes. The incentives could
diminish for development agencies to focus on
complex institutional reforms that cannot readily
be shown to have tangible results and cannot be
explained in terms of bilateral donors’ national
interest. In this possible future, the emphasis on
country-level institutional strengthening would
likely be displaced by a redoubled focus on direct
interventions in sectors and increasing attention
to global public goods, begging many questions
about sustainability.
While the Working Group contends that its
proposals will contribute to the future relevance
and effectiveness of the PFM discipline, they
do pose nancial and opportunity costs in the
short term. In looking at these proposals from
the point of view of an international development
agency, there is a question about why one agency
would invest in signicant new research and
learning that will benet the eld as a whole,
allowing free riding. Leadership will be needed at
an institutional level, along with some willingness
to direct nancial resources to these ideas or new
approaches with the wider strategic rationale in
mind. Active experimentation and learning will be
required from the outset. Leaders within the PFM
discipline might take up these ideas, and progress
might be kick-started by funding for one or more
of the proposals under a pilot approach.
Organization of the report
In the following chapter, we dene PFM and
take stock of how it has evolved as an area of
work and a focus of development assistance
over the past two decades. We describe the
emergence, conventions, and approaches of the
“discipline” of PFM within the overall eld of
international development. Finally, we review the
standard objectives of PFM and consider the case
for refreshing and expanding them.
In Chapter 3, we discuss how to build on
and improve the existing “closed” model of
PFM. We explore how to drive improvements in
external support and how to make choices among
technical advice options more meaningful. The
chapter considers whether there may be a need
and opportunity to accelerate knowledge sharing
and learning in technical advice for PFM and then
discusses whether increased contestation among
different intervention options and ideas could
drive greater effectiveness and encourage more
meaningful government choice.
In Chapter 4, we examine the possibilities that
may emerge if we envisage PFM as an “open”
system and consider questions regarding how
PFM inuences public policy. The chapter begins
with an examination of how PFM can be related
Chapter 1. Introduction:
Setting the Agenda
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
9
more directly to service delivery and development
results, and the need for PFM conventions to
evolve in response to new evidence. It then reviews
how PFM can support major policy changes and
promote the consideration of trade-offs among
policy objectives, including socioeconomic
priorities.
Finally, in Chapter 5, we put forward seven
proposals for how to put this agenda into
practice. The chapter concludes with some
propositions for further debate and by addressing
the case for change and the incentives of
development assistance providers.
10
This chapter provides a framing of the core
subject matter to be discussed through the
report—managing public nance, broadly
dened, and public nancial management
more specically. It sets out key denitions and
takes stock of how PFM has evolved as an area of
work and a focus of development assistance over
the past two decades. It describes the emergence
of a “discipline” of PFM within the overall eld
of international development—complete with its
own set of approaches and “conventions” for the
desirable operational performance of PFM. The
impact and limitations of contemporary ideas about
applying problem-based and adaptive approaches
to PFM are explored. The chapter then reviews
the standard “trinity” of PFM objectives and
considers the case for refreshing and expanding
them. It proposes broadening the objectives to
address additional considerations such as scal
risks, policy change and reprioritization, modes
and quality of service delivery, macroeconomic
stability, fairness and legitimacy, and democratic
accountability.


The phrase “managing public nance” directs
attention toward a large conceptual territory
with little certainty about its boundaries. It
comprises objectives and policies on the one
hand and institutional arrangements and systems
on the other. It covers a broad swath of state
engagement with the economy and society.
Fiscal policy, budgets, budgetary processes,
expenditure management, nancial management,
accountability, and nance ministries all sit within
the domain of managing public nance. Finding
a single organizing framework for all of these
dimensions and elements has proved difcult.
The narrower concept of “public nancial
management” has emerged as a more distinct
and tractable domain within this larger and
conceptually more uncertain context. It is
delimited by the institutional arrangements that
support public nance objectives. In international
development circles, PFM has become an
increasingly proprietary term that is “owned” by
a distinct group of professionals. While there is no
consensus, this report follows a recent formulation
by the International Monetary Fund (IMF):
PFM in the narrowest, and perhaps most
traditional, sense is concerned with
how governments manage the budget
in its established phases—formulation,
approval, and execution.…[I]ts relevance
in scal policymaking has evolved
over time,…broadened its focus…to all
aspects of managing public resources,
including resource mobilization and debt
management, with a progressive extension
to the medium- to long-term implications
and risks to public nances from today’s
policy decisions. The coverage of PFM has
thus expanded from the narrowly dened
central government budget to all levels of
government and the broader public sector,
including state enterprises and public-
private partnerships. Furthermore, PFM
is now seen as an ‘umbrella’ denition,
covering a set of systems aimed at
producing information, processes, and
rules that can help support scal policy-
making as well as provide instruments for
its implementation. (Cangiano, Curristine
& Lazare, 2013b, pp. 1-2)
Using this broad denition, PFM refers to
the systems that connect public resources
with social and economic policy while serving
the wider nancial purposes of accounting
and accountability. In its economic and policy
functions, PFM supports analysis and decision
making for government allocation, distribution,
and stabilization objectives and choices—
principally through the budget (Musgrave &
Musgrave, 1989). In its nancial functions, PFM
covers the use of money for public purposes. It
2. MANAGING PUBLIC FINANCE: A REAPPRAISAL
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
11
involves an accounting function for revenue and
expenditure and a system of accountability to
support public scrutiny (Hughes, 2018).

context
PFM is not an independent variable. In seeking
to improve development results, factors such as
the wider public management systems in play,
the social and political environment, and the
capacity of government cannot be disregarded. In
considering the long chain of connections linking
government policy choices to development results
(Annex B), there is no institutional dimension
which is primus inter pares.
Broader developments in public
management
The 1990s were a momentous time for public
management in general. Dominant ideas about
how to improve public sector performance,
however that slippery term may have been dened,
were changing—and not just in Anglophone
advanced economies. Prior to that period, views
on improving public sector performance were
essentially “managerialist,” with the idea that
organizations would perform as well as they were
managed and that similar managerial skills were
needed in the public and private sectors (Drucker,
1974). These ideas had been dominant since the
1970s and had themselves seemed revolutionary,
a promising way to open up the previously “self-
contained world” of public administration and
its arcane traditions (Sayre, 1958). Over time,
however, this approach proved unconvincing in
the face of the evident difculties in reforming
large public bureaucracies.
1
By the 1990s, new
thinking had emerged that the route to public
management improvements lay in rethinking
the institutional arrangements that underpinned
them—the structures and incentives of the public
sector. Research insights about the nature of
public sector institutions (Bakir & Jarvis, 2018)
contributed to new ideas in the public sectors
of advanced economies (Gore, 1995; OECD,
1995) and in developing countries (World Bank,
1997). How public ofcials approached their task
remained important, but this was a time when the
formal and informal rules that motivated those staff
were now thought to be both more fundamental
and more tractable.
2
This rewiring of public management was more
evolution than Copernican revolution. While
institutional reform became more central as the
point of entry to public sector improvements, not
everything changed. The shift toward institutional
innovation, and away from the stability and
certainty of merit and hierarchy, left in place
several assumptions that still inuence PFM
thinking today. For example, the general approach
to PFM has continued to assume that improvements
can be achieved by lling institutional gaps; that
the public sector is homogenous enough that
lessons concerning policy implementation are
generalizable across sectors, implying that what
has worked in health could work in education;
and that the public sector runs on somewhat
mechanical principles—get the machine right and
it can execute any feasible and legitimate political
directives.
The implications of country context
Allowing for country context and other
distinctive political economy factors has always
been challenging for reform initiatives. The
public sector reform menu during the last three
decades has been extensive (Annex C). But
critics of this period of busy institutional change
point out that, while much was being learned,
the study of public management had become
unhelpfully “decontextualized” (Pollitt, 2008).
They argued that the eld was prone to offering
ill-tting reforms in the name of modernization.
The obvious challenge for those seeking to
learn lessons has always been that, if context is
dominant, few principles can be applied beyond a
high level of generality.
Political and contextual factors mean that
the same institutional arrangements for PFM
may have different effects in different settings.
12
Although some observers suggest that recent
progress toward a normative eld of public
management has been limited because of the
problem of understanding and controlling for
context (Roberts, 2018), there has been some
progress within the development community—at
least in scoping the territory. Research shows that
seemingly similar institutions work differently
in different contexts. For example, social
accountability and “demand-side” mechanisms
can channel local expenditure exibility toward
higher-priority results, or they can be blocked
(Ringold, 2012; Sheely, 2014),
3
or they can
be actively distorted in the presence of non-
programmatic political parties and vote buying
(Keefer, 2013; Khemani, 2013).
4
In the same
vein, similar budgetary institutions can support
ministerial accountability or, by contrast, allow
overspending (Alesina, Hausmann, Hommes &
Stein, 1999).
Political context also affects PFM reform
possibilities. It can be harder, for example, to
implement “basic” reforms that focus on control
of public expenditures (including commitment
control, prevention of leakages in procurement and
payroll, or reliable accounting) in political contexts
where leakages benet well-connected interest
groups than it is to overcome more advanced
technical challenges such as the introduction of
medium-term expenditure frameworks (MTEFs)
(Fritz et al., 2017). Further down the results
chain, Batley and McLoughlin (2015) show that
the political challenges to service delivery reform
are affected by the characteristics of the particular
sector and by the legal assignment of functions
to different levels of government. All in all, it is
hardly surprising that general principles are hard
to nd.
The role of government capacity and
capability
There is a large and occasionally rather
abstract literature concerning the development
of government “capacity,” with a growing focus
now on building the “capability” of nance
ministries. While there are no stable denitions
of either term (Morgan, 2006), capacity can
be usefully seen as the endowment of human,
nancial, technical, and physical resources
available to an organization or a government, while
capability captures the practical reality of whether
or not that capacity results in the achievement of
specic tasks. Recent research has pushed beyond
the traditional focus on capacity inputs, and
whether that capacity should be built or otherwise
acquired, to emphasize the functional capability
of nance ministries as an essential ingredient
of effective PFM (Allen & Grigoli, 2012; Allen,
Grigoli & Howard, 2011; Allen & Krause, 2013;
Dressel & Brumby, 2009; and Krause, Hadley,
Mustapha & Welham, 2016).
There is a risk that denitional uncertainties
leave capacity and capability as the default
culprits when performance failures cannot
otherwise be explained. Such an approach
cannot identify specic changes that need to be
made (Zafarullah & Huque, 2012). That said,
the growing literature on these issues is usefully
highlighting neglected factors in the “production
function” of a central nance agency, “such as the
culture, morale and incentives of the organization;
the quality and experience of its management
and staff; the organizational structure; the
business processes that support and underpin the
organization; and the supporting information and
human resource management systems” (Allen et
al., 2011, p. 4).
PFM as a “professional discipline”
and its conventions
Public nancial management is its own
distinctive eld in international development.
This section considers the reasons for that
distinctive signicance and what underpins it. It
argues that PFM can be viewed as a professional
“discipline” with its own conventions, which have
a powerful effect on how the technical advice
provided by PFM experts is understood, codied,
and deployed.
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
13
The importance of PFM in development
assistance
Donor countries champion and support PFM
for the rather obvious reason that how public
nances are managed plays an important part
in the achievement, or not, of development
results (Andrews, 2007; Cangiano et al.,
2013b). There is little dispute about the essential
features of PFM institutional arrangements that,
at a minimum, provide nancing for sectors in
line with policy objectives, ensure timely and
predictable resource ows to agencies and between
levels of government, and assist in the effective
management and use of resources at the facility
level (Andrews, 2007; Cangiano et al., 2013b).
5
These contributions to service delivery are
reasonably assumed to contribute, by extension,
to the achievement of sector outcomes. There
is a matching consensus among development
agencies that arrangements for ensuring aggregate
scal discipline are the key to the long-term
sustainability of government policy actions to
improve service delivery and development results.
As discussed below, however, there are some signs
of growing uncertainty about the right sequencing
of these two objectives.
Donor countries have placed a greater emphasis
on the importance of PFM in lower-income
countries since the 1990s.
6
Ofcial nance
providers are prepared to invest considerable
effort in assessing the performance of PFM
arrangements, seeking preemptive assurance that
nances will be used as intended and used well.
Arguably, they sometimes trade off development
impact against duciary risk when sacricing
programs that are effective but not accountable
enough (Bain, Booth & Wild, 2016; Derviş,
Chandy, Kharas, Medler & Unger, 2011).
7
The
move toward general budget support in the
2000s—and then away from it again in the 2010s—
underscored concerns about managing duciary
risk (de Renzio, 2006). Limited risk tolerance on
the part of donor countries, particularly during the
time of austerity and heightened skepticism about
the utility of foreign aid following the global
nancial crisis of 2007–08, has undoubtedly been
a major impetus for the recent focus on PFM.
The scale and composition of international
support for PFM
Measured in nancial terms, PFM is
a substantial program of development
cooperation activity. Recent research shows the
trends in development nance, including ofcial
development assistance (ODA) and other ofcial
ows (OOF) from governments and multilateral
organizations, directed toward technical assistance
for PFM (AlphaBeta, 2018). Rapid growth in the
rst part of the 2000s remained buoyant into the
2010s, with average annual spending of US$ 1.86
billion globally between 2012 and 2016 (Figure 2).
The picture is uneven across geographical areas,
with absolute spending per year in Latin America
increasing by 217 percent between 2002–06 and
2012–16 and overtaking the amounts directed to
Sub-Saharan Africa, which increased by only 6
percent in absolute terms over the same period.
International support for PFM has grown faster
(86 percent) than overall volumes of development
nance (69 percent) over the same period,
suggesting an uptick in PFM’s relative importance.
If general budget support and other programmatic
nancing linked to strengthening the scal sector
were to be included, the gures for PFM support
would be even higher.
14

(US$ billions)
Source:AlphaBeta(2018).
Notes on Figures 2 and 3
External sources of nancing for PFM reform: Disbursements from external sources in support of PFM
reformwereobtainedfromasampleof18countries.Forthosecountries,in-depthanalysisandadjustment
ofexternalfundingdataforPFMunderthe15111codeontheDACdatabasefrom2002–16,usingaddional
sourcessuchasdonorprojectdocumentsandalternavedatabases,revealedthat46%ofdonor-reported
projectdisbursementsover2002–16wereinfactPFMreform-relatedspending.Theremainingdisbursements
wereremovedfromthetotals.
Analysis of internal spending in Figure 3: The totalsspentby governmentsfromdomesc sourceswere
derivedfromanalysisof7ofthe18countriesandesmaonsfortheother11.
Denion of reform areas: See endnotes.
8
Figure 3: Internal and external funding by PFM reform area for
a basket of countries (US$ billions)
Source:AlphaBeta(2018).
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
Core FMIS
infrastructure
Budget execuon
2002-2006 2007-2011 2012-2016
Budget
formulaon &
authorizaon
Budget evaluaon
35
30
25
20
15
10
5
0
Expenditure side
reforms
Revenue-side reforms
Accounng and
reporng
Treasury Single
Accounts
Forecasng and
strategic budgeng
PFM legislaon
External audit and
monitoring
Internal audit and
control
External funding (ODA & OOF) for PFM reform 2002-16 in
nominal terms
US$ billions
$10
$5.0
2002-2006
$8.5
2007-2011
$9.3
2012-2016
$9
$8
$7
$6
$5
$4
$3
$2
$1
$0
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
15
Recent attempts to disaggregate PFM reform
spending indicate priority areas and dominant
funders. The most signicant areas of spending
within PFM—looking at a sample of 18 countries
and including governments’ own allocations
as well as development assistance—have been
core nancial management information system
(FMIS) infrastructure and budget execution
reforms in procurement, service delivery, and
payroll (Figure 3). These funding gures may
understate the volume and relative signicance
of external support for PFM, as they include
the OECD Development Assistance Committee
(DAC) category of “public nance management”
but exclude the separate categories for domestic
revenue mobilization, local government nance,
and public procurement (AlphaBeta, 2018).
9
Yet
all of these categories are considered as part of this
report’s “umbrella” denition of PFM, following
Cangiano et al. (2013b). The most signicant
providers of external nance for PFM, by some
considerable margin, are the World Bank, Inter-
American Development Bank (IADB), and Asian
Development Bank (ADB). Despite the prominent
role and inuence of IMF advice on PFM, the
nancial scale of its capacity development support
is modest (AlphaBeta, 2018).
There is some evidence that PFM is becoming
a larger component of sector assistance
programs as well. The World Bank, as the largest
PFM assistance provider, is a guide. The growing
relative signicance of PFM as an area of focus
for development assistance is illustrated by its
share in other World Bank portfolios (Annex D).
In health and education programs, PFM has grown
to a share of roughly 9 percent over the past 15
years, and in governance it has held steady at
around 50 percent over the past decade.
Data on the volume and disaggregation of PFM
support are interesting, but also unreliable.
Despite apparent trends, particular caution is
required in using or interpreting the data, as there
are well-known problems of collection, recording,
reporting, and comparison. The overall quality
of available data is poor, and this remains a live
research agenda (Annex E). For full discussion of
these data, see AlphaBeta (2018).
The PFM “discipline” in international
development
The emergence of PFM as a professional
discipline
An academic or subject discipline is a common
language, spoken by a select group.
10
It
comprises a focus area for discussion, concepts
and theories for organizing that discussion, and
some institutional arrangements for imposing
discipline by correcting or at least identifying
those who have erred.
11
A professional discipline goes one step further;
it is an academic discipline plus career paths
with opportunities for advancement in work
and reputations (Nikitina, 2005). As such, it
brings together a “sociology of the profession—
career incentives, norms, socialization patterns”
(Naidu, Rodrik & Zucman, 2019, p. 1).
International development has few professional
disciplines. This is not to say that development
is without expertise or research, but it has few
distinctive bodies of knowledge and even fewer
that combine such knowledge with distinct career
paths. Agronomists and epidemiologists draw on
rich bodies of academic work, but do not form
large cadres within development organizations
with clear lines of career advancement. Economics
is the most evident professional discipline found
in the development eld (Stein, 2008). Although
still some distance behind economics, PFM is
emerging as a distinct professional discipline
in international development, with a common
language and an associated career path.
12
PFM experts act as the guardians of the
professional discipline
PFM expertise is carried by a distinct body of
staff within the development community. Much
of the expertise in PFM in ofcial development
agencies is concentrated in the IMF, World
Bank, IADB, and other international nancial
16
institutions (IFIs). The degree to which these staff
adhere to both explicit technical knowledge and
tacit knowledge is noted in the IMF case, with a
recent high-level review group concluding that
“…part of the Fund’s success has been that it is
a strongly normed organization, with many staff
deeply committed to the mission and mandate of
the Fund, to professional and disciplinary norms,
and to the often implicit culture and norms of the
organization” (IMF, 2018a, p. 6). Many staff in the
IMF Fiscal Affairs Department are former nance
ministry ofcials and most are economists by
training, with both factors serving to reinforce the
sense of PFM as a select professional discipline.
The nancial management and procurement
cadres in the World Bank form “chapters” of
the PFM discipline. The interchange of staff
between IFIs and client country nance ministries,
especially from developing countries, strengthens
the disciplinary connections (Fritz, Fialho Lopes,
Hedger, Tavakoli & Krause, 2011).
13
Once located within international cooperation
agencies, many PFM experts remain there
and envisage completing their careers there.
In an exploratory survey of self-identied PFM
specialists undertaken for this report,
14
the
majority of respondents identied most closely
with general nancial management, economics,
or governance elds. Their related professional
experience was gained almost equally across
public sector, consulting, international
organization, and academic work. Respondents
were overwhelmingly senior (with 15 or more
years of experience), and most had spent their
careers in the public sector or in an international
development organization. Most of those who
responded to the survey stated that the nature
of their work was as staff of a single, generally
multilateral, organization (as opposed to as an
expert working with multiple organizations). A
majority of respondents envisaged their future
careers continuing in an international development
agency.
Beyond the ofcial development agencies, a
large cadre of international PFM experts are
located in consulting and accounting rms,
universities, research institutes, and think
tanks. Although not revealed to a great extent
by the survey, these experts are prevalent in the
extensive and growing literature on PFM issues.
There is also a large community of independent
PFM experts, or those with multiple afliations,
who work as technical advisers on projects and
other assistance interventions in lower-income
countries.
Experts from all of these different constituencies
within the PFM discipline learn from each
other. Respondents identied the views of
counterparts and other stakeholders, along with
their own professional practitioner experience,
as the most signicant in forming their views.
Almost all survey respondents were familiar with
formal assessment frameworks (Annex F). The
most commonly cited were PEFA, the IMF Fiscal
Transparency Code, and the Tax Administration
Diagnostic Assessment Tool (TADAT).
Strong professional associations offset some
gaps in theory and evidence
PFM experts have a common professional
language and frame of reference, underpinned
by three structural features of PFM. First, despite
many political and constitutional differences,
similar PFM processes have developed in most
countries, represented by an annual cycle of scal
decision making, implementation, and review
centered on the budget process.
15
While there are
many complicating factors, not least that these
stages overlap and that multiple agencies are
involved in each one (Andrews et al., 2014), the
annual milestones in the budget cycle provide a
way of structuring discussion about PFM. Second,
strong forms of professional association have
emerged for specic subgroups in PFM, such as
auditors and accountants (Squire & Beazley, 2016;
Unegbu, 2014). Professional bodies set widely
accepted standards for individual and organizational
behaviors, ranging from the International Public
Sector Accounting Standards
16
to the Standards
for Internal Controls.
17
Disciplinary enforcement
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
17
is primarily reputational, but some additional
force is given by the membership basis of some
of these organizations—usually at the individual
level and with the possibility, at least in theory, of
cancellation.
18
Third, the articulation of standard
PFM objectives in the late 1990s (described below)
has had a signicant inuence in establishing and
consolidating a sense of shared purpose among
PFM experts.
The challenge for the PFM discipline is to
provide practical guidance, because the
“institutions matter” mantra alone does not
get us far. The underpinning theory for PFM is
at the same high level of generality as in other
governance domains, all of which have found
it difcult to dene a practical approach to
uniting concerns for due process, efciency and
economic growth, and politics and inclusion
(Andrews, 2008a, 2008b; de Renzio, 2013; Plant,
Stalebrink & Vasavada, 2010; Thomas, 2010).
19
The evidence base concerning what works where
and under what circumstances remains too patchy
to supplement the theoretical shortcomings,
20
and
the PFM discipline thus nds itself without a strong
theoretical or empirical anchor for its practical
recommendations (Key, 1940). In response, it has
found two ways of navigating past these gaps to
develop recommendations for action: focusing on
a general set of conventions for the operational
performance of PFM processes and, increasingly,
emphasizing local, context-specic problem
solving as an approach to PFM reform.
Strong conventions as the mainstay
of PFM
The specication of a set of conventions
concerning the desired operational performance
of PFM processes has emerged as the dominant
disciplinary approach. The increasing emphasis
on consensus-based conventions in PFM is
reected in the swelling numbers of assessment
frameworks and tools (Annex F; PEFA Secretariat,
2018b). Their proliferation does not signal an
end to contentious debates such as that on the
degree to which performance incentives should
be emphasized in PFM. Some of the dimensions
covered in these frameworks are based on
internationally agreed standards, but many are not.
While the organizations or groups responsible for
devising and rening the frameworks are clear that
they are intended as a basis for discussion rather
than as conclusions regarding actions that need to
be taken,
21
they are undoubtedly normative.
These frameworks and the conventions
they reect provide a powerful and succinct
codication of the tacit knowledge of many
generations of practitioners, gained over
many years and in many contexts.
22
Proposing
conformity with the conventions is tantamount to
learning from others about how to strengthen the
“scal machinery” that is put in place to address
the common pool problem in public expenditure
management (Annett, 2002; Hallerberg &
Yläoutinen, 2010; von Hagen & Harden, 1995;
Wyplosz, 2011).
23
A similar picture emerged
for tax administration in the 1990s and 2000s,
where a standard set of reforms such as semi-
autonomous revenue authorities developed based
on ideas surrounding new public management and
observed practices in advanced economies (Dom
& Miller, 2018).
24
While there has long been some
acknowledgment that different PFM objectives
require different emphases in PFM systems,
25
there has been an equally long-held assumption
among technical assistance providers that, for
all practical purposes, the PFM conventions are
independent of any sector policies and objectives
(Premchand, 1993).
A specic denition and usage of “PFM
conventions” is applied for the purposes of
clarity in this report. We use PFM conventions to
refer to the normative assumptions about desirable
“operational performance of key elements of the
PFM system” based on “international standards
and good practices on crucial aspects of PFM, as
identied by experienced practitioners” and as
expressed in standard PFM assessment frameworks
such as PEFA and TADAT (PEFA Secretariat,
2016, pp. 1–4). Those assessment frameworks
typically include graduated performance scores.
18
There is a normative assumption that a stronger
and more capable PFM system is one in which
processes and procedures fulll requirements
at the top end of the measured scales. The PFM
conventions might thus be represented by the
highest-scoring attributes captured by the various
assessment frameworks. A distinction is drawn
here between the PFM conventions, the PFM
assessment frameworks that incorporate and
represent them, and the PFM processes that form
the technical building blocks for the overall PFM
system (Annex A).
While the PFM conventions are generally
viewed in terms of their contribution to a
standard set of PFM objectives, evidence to
support that relationship is limited. Various
studies nd no statistically signicant relationship
between a PEFA-based measure of overall PFM
quality and the scal balance—for both non-
fragile and fragile states (Mustapha & Long,
2019; Fritz, Sweet & Verhoeven, 2014; Alesina et
al., 1999; von Hagen & Harden, 1995). Evidence
is more positive on the impact of MTEFs on scal
discipline (World Bank, 2012a). The imposition
of scal rules (numerical limits on budgetary
aggregates), driven by recent scal consolidation
experiences (IMF, 2010; Lassen, 2010; OECD,
2010), has had at best a marginal impact on actual
behaviors. Finally, countries that credibly enforce
penalties for non-compliance do tend to collect
more taxes (Mustapha & Long, 2019).
Problem-based and adaptive approaches
Problem-based and adaptive approaches are
increasingly supplementing the disciplinary
emphasis on PFM conventions. The “new
realist”
26
approach did not originate in PFM but
has found particular resonance there (CID, 2014;
Andrews, 2013; Andrews, Pritchett & Woolcock,
2012; Blum, Manning & Srivastava, 2012; Booth,
2014; Booth & Unsworth, 2014; World Bank,
2000, 2012b). The approach rests on two insights.
First, it is hard to predict what will change the
behavior of public ofcials in a given context.
Conformity with the PFM conventions might
have a positive impact on behavior or, given
complex local conditions, it might not. Second,
it is expensive and difcult to nd out what is
really happening. We can perhaps see what the
“concentrated agents” at the center are doing, but
it is hard to see what behaviors may be changing
among “distributed agents” such as “budgeters,
accountants, and such in sector ministries,
provinces, and districts” (Andrews, 2014, p. 1).
27
The information problem undermines the
“conformity as lesson learning” idea at both
ends. On the theory side, the behaviors and
procedures identied as preferred standards
might represent the distilled essence of what
was claimed rather than what was done. On the
practice side, the emulation of those changes might
not be genuine, with changed rules disguising
unchanged behaviors. Proponents of a problem-
based and adaptive approach argue that, while
an understanding of performance failures can be
informed by wider lessons and experiences, the
specic causes and purposes of a given apparent
dysfunction have to be determined case by case
through “guided incremental experimentation”
(Pritchett et al., 2013, p. 48). They assert that
institutional reforms are addressing “adaptive”
rather than “technical” problems.
28
In its
draft guidance on improving PFM, the PEFA
Secretariat (2019, p. 27) highlights contingency
to country context in deciding whether a formal
comprehensive reform strategy or an informal
iterative approach would be more appropriate.
These approaches have emerged amid an
increasingly nuanced understanding of the
signicance of political context. The insight
that PFM is entangled with politics is not new.
There has long been discussion of “big politics,”
with identiable elites driven by the self-interest
of remaining in power or in ofce and of self-
enrichment. That phenomenon is well-documented
in weak governance environments with “extractive
institutions” (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2012) or in
“limited access orders,” in which the consensus
among elites about rent distribution is unstable
(North, Wallis, Webb & Weingast, 2007). There
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
19
is also a growing awareness of the signicance of
the “small politics” reected in interministerial
rivalries, union concerns, and cadre and
bureaucratic rivalries.
29
Recent work in this area
is moving beyond broad analyses, pointing the
way toward more grounded theories about why
institutions are working as they are and about
how change might be feasible (Booth, 2011; Fritz,
Levy & Ort, 2014; Fritz et al., 2017; Yanguas &
Hulme, 2014).
Bridging conventions and adaptation
Using PFM conventions as reference points in
assessing performance and following adaptive
approaches to reform design need not be in
tension. Adaptation and agnosticism are not
necessarily good things in themselves. They
are part of the general tactical case for cautious
incrementalism in reforms, along the lines of
the observations made by Lindblom (1959)
concerning “muddling through” within large
bureaucracies and by Pressman and Wildavsky
(1973) on policy implementation. Those are
rational ways of managing complexity and the
uncertainty inherent in predicting the exact
consequences of reforms at each stage. But
reforms have to begin somewhere. It is necessary
to “develop initial responses which are then
modied over the life of the project” (Brinkerhoff
& Ingle, 1989, p. 490). After all, it is “difcult
to hold the attention of those eager for progress
and clear answers with responses that amount to
‘Well, I’m not sure, but let’s explore this more and
perhaps we can generate some ideas…’” (Grindle,
2013, p. 400). Conformity with conventions can
provide that starting point.
30
“In reality, reform
strategies need to be both problem-driven and
solution driven” (Allen, 2018, p. 402). This is a
point echoed in a recent study of PFM reforms in
eight East Asian countries, which concludes that
“‘innovative’ means—by denition—not holding
unwaveringly to predetermined plans and not
insistently using standard techniques in standard
ways” (So, Woolcock, April, Hughes & Smithers,
2018, p. 4).
Guiding objectives of PFM and their
evolution
The purpose of PFM must drive the content
and the approach. The PFM discipline offers
its own distinctive set of objectives which the
discipline holds up as the ultimate justication for
the conventions it recommends. These standard
PFM objectives have come to be seen as universal,
transcending the specicities of country and
context. There is a real world case for refreshing
and expanding them. This section proposes a
broadening of the objectives to address additional
considerations such as scal risks, policy change
and reprioritization, modes and quality of service
delivery, macroeconomic stability, fairness and
legitimacy, and democratic accountability.
The rise and dominance of standard
PFM objectives
PFM has achieved a broad normative
consensus that conformity with the established
conventions is necessary, if not sufcient, to
achieve a standard set of objectives. Over the
last 25 years, PFM reforms in lower-income
countries have been widely assessed in terms of
their contribution to what is often referred to in
the literature as “desirable budgetary outcomes”
(Campos & Pradhan, 1996; PEFA Secretariat,
2016; Schick, 1998a; World Bank, 1998).
Although originally described merely as desirable
outcomes, they have come to dene the purpose
of the PFM system and have become the de
facto objectives. They are widely viewed as the
gateway through which PFM contributes to other
government objectives.
In one of their classic formulations, the three
standard objectives are:
Aggregate scal discipline – Budget totals
should be the result of explicit, enforced
decisions; they should not merely accommodate
spending demands. These totals should be set
before individual spending decisions are made,
and should be sustainable over the medium term
and beyond.
20
Allocative efciency – Expenditures should
be based on government priorities and on
effectiveness of public programs. The budget
system should spur reallocation from lesser to
higher priorities and from less to more effective
programs.
Operational efciencyAgencies should
produce goods and services at a cost that
achieves ongoing efciency gains and (to the
extent appropriate) is competitive with market
prices” (Schick, 1998a, p. 2, developed from
the original framework by Campos & Pradhan,
1996).
These objectives emerged originally to
cover public expenditure management—
as a narrower domain than contemporary
PFM. It is useful to recall that these objectives
were the product of their time. They reected a
preoccupation with scal stability, top-down
expenditure control, and efforts to bring order
and restraint to bottom-up budgeting approaches.
They emerged as attention was beginning to shift
from government policies toward the institutional
arrangements that enabled or incentivized policy
making and implementation. Most particularly,
they came into being at a time when a normative
version of the “Washington Consensus”
(Williamson, 2004)—arguably differing from
its original intention to observe rather than to
recommend—was ascendant. The objectives
were led by an emphasis on scal discipline and
supported by a view, emerging at the time, that
incrementalism might need to be challenged in
order to achieve this discipline.
31
This standard trinity of PFM objectives is
strongly value-laden, but was not intended
as hierarchical. The objectives were originally
envisaged as interdependent, without any
hierarchy or proposed sequencing (Campos &
Pradhan, 1996; World Bank, 1998). Contrary
to this vision, however, they are often treated
in practice as three levels of priority, with scal
discipline at the apex. This point is illustrated
by the proliferation of numerical scal rules and
targets over the past 15 years, which “have often
been seen as a means for addressing all scal
problems—chiey rising decits and debt levels
but also accountability and responsibility gaps—
while relegating other vital PFM elements to a
supporting role” (Cangiano et al., 2013b, p. 5).
Some institutional arrangements, including scal
rules, scal councils, multiyear frameworks,
and accrual regimes, actively reinforce scal
discipline as the primary and dominant concern.
This shift arguably represents a misreading of
two formative case studies from the 1980s and
early 1990s—New Zealand and Australia—which
heavily inuenced the objectives, but for which
the relative emphasis among objectives differed
(Campbell, 2001; Keating & Holmes, 1990;
Schick, 1996; Scott, Bushnell & Sallee, 1990).
These standard objectives have a powerful grip
on PFM work, and addressing scal discipline and
related considerations of nancial control is often
the recommended rst step for reforms (Brooke,
2003; Diamond, 2013). The consequence of this
assumed rank ordering of the objectives is that
the focus on scal discipline has the potential to
override values such as improving public services
or moving toward more equal income distribution.
Discussion of these PFM objectives should not
be confused with government policy choices
in the context of their domestic public policy
framework. We refer to PFM “objectives”
throughout this report because that is how they
have been dened and described in the public
nance literature. Annex B sets out a framework
for domestic public policy, and it is clear that these
PFM objectives are at a distinctly higher and more
generic level than the choices, actions, and results
that one particular government might make, or
wish to make. It is more accurate to view the
objectives as an orientation for the PFM discipline.
They are a way of structuring problem analysis
in public nance (Dunn, 1988) and a means to
reduce complexity through a set of concepts that
“simplify and abstract from reality with limiting
assumptions” (Love & Stockdale-Otárola, 2017,
p. 17).
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
21
The objectives of scal discipline, allocative
efciency, and operational efciency have been
widely adopted and applied by the international
PFM community. The consensus around the
three objectives has been entrenched by their
incorporation into standard PFM assessment tools
such as the PEFA framework (PEFA Secretariat,
2016). They have been highly effective in shifting
attention from theoretical concerns to real-world
recommendations for PFM reforms (Andrews,
2007; PEFA Secretariat, 2016). They have proven
remarkably durable, and their original formulation
remains largely unchanged in substance almost 25
years later. Allocative efciency tends now to be
described as the “strategic allocation of resources”
and operational efciency has become “efcient
service delivery” (PEFA Secretariat, 2016), but
they appear to have changed little in substance
from their formulations two decades ago (Schick,
1998a; World Bank, 1998). Although PEFA now
refers to scal risks in its description of scal
discipline (PEFA Secretariat, 2016), it is much less
apparent that the explicit focus on service delivery
has yet succeeded in addressing the dimensions of
quality and accessibility alongside efciency.
32
The standard objectives remain valid but

PFM is often presented as a set of technical
processes that are neutral to particular policy
directions. The approach to managing public
nances that has held sway for some three decades
views a relatively standard set of institutional
arrangements as essential in limiting the ability of
politicians to use revenues raised from the many to
satisfy the few and thus deny them corresponding
opportunities to privilege their base and overspend
(von Hagen, 2006). The dominant “institutional”
perspective that emerged from studies of budgeting
in OECD countries in the 1990s sees the budget
primarily as an instrument to control decits
and debt levels through a set of institutional
arrangements to negotiate and adjudicate among
competing interests (von Hagen, 1998; von Hagen
& Harden, 1995). Some consensus emerged that
a common “scal machinery” (Premchand, 2000)
for achieving this could be identied and that this
machinery was policy-neutral: it would be t for
purpose across a range of policy directions and
institutional settings.
In reality, the PFM system cannot easily be
disconnected from policy for two reasons:
the need to be responsive to policy change
and the need to support fairness in outcomes.
The standard PFM objectives are silent on these
challenges. This is not a criticism—the objectives
have performed strongly as a guide to expenditure
management and as a framework for budgeting,
and they have set the scene for practical
considerations about the nature of the institutional
arrangements needed to achieve the objectives.
But it is becoming clear that these challenges
cannot be ignored.
Major global and national policy priorities—
such as climate change, inequality, and
infrastructure development—are demanding
a fundamental reorientation or rebalancing
in public nance and how it is managed. By
contrast, PFM systems are designed to orient
scal outcomes toward caution and inertia. PFM
conveys norms that may predispose policy makers
toward short-term scal restraint or retrenchment
in pursuit of stabilization. At the same time,
PFM has always embodied a tendency toward
“incrementalism” in budget formulation, not least
because of the complexity in costing and nancing
signicant policy reorientation (Wildavsky, 1992).
Incremental changes are a pragmatic response
to complexity and a way to reduce conict over
resource allocation. The advent of multiyear
frameworks and accrual regimes has reinforced
multiyear continuity and stability in PFM.
The power of the standard trinity of objectives
has derived from their seemingly neutral
and universally relevant nature. There are
presumably no circumstances under which scal
indiscipline, allocative inefciency, or operational
inefciency would be desirable. Yet policy agility
in the face of pressing economic, social, and
22
environmental challenges, and the distribution
of income to address questions of fairness and
legitimacy, are also important. The current PFM
objectives are not technically disputed or wrong.
The problem is that they are incomplete, and the
prominence that their success and inuence have
given them is stiing the attention needed to other
valuable socioeconomic objectives.
Updating and expanding the standard
PFM objectives
Recognizing the reality of multiple
perspectives on PFM
Despite the prominence of the standard PFM
objectives, underpinned by an extensive
literature, there is no consensus about their
theoretical basis. At least three different
perspectives have informed thinking about the
purpose and development of PFM. The dominant
inuence on the standard formulation of objectives
has been the institutional perspective (Campos
& Pradhan, 1996; Schick, 1998a; von Hagen,
1998; von Hagen & Harden, 1995), which draws
on the insights of public choice theory and new
institutional economics. Yet de Renzio (2009,
2013) highlights two alternative ways to interpret
budgeting objectives. An administrative perspec-
tive emphasizes the nancial functions of PFM
through management systems and associated
integrity and compliance mechanisms (Cangiano
et al., 2013b; Diamond, 2013; Hughes, 2018). An
economic perspective draws on public economics
to consider scal and budget policies (Musgrave
& Musgrave, 1989). While there are some areas
of overlap among these three ways of considering
PFM, their differing content provides a prima
facie case for considering whether to expand the
standard objectives.
PFM has always been broader than the
budget process, which is the main focus of
the dominant institutional perspective, and it
has continued to expand in its scope since the
1990s. Beyond budgeting itself, the PFM system
represents the regulations and procedures needed
to ensure compliance with budgetary decisions.
Accordingly, “management systems must also
be in place to execute the budget in line with
resource allocation decisions, (i.e. resource use is
accounted for, monitored, reported and audited);
treasury operations exist so this execution takes
place smoothly in terms of cash availability; and
resource use is nanced efciently through debt
management operations” (Diamond, 2013, p. 12).
The purview of PFM has also grown markedly in
recent years to incorporate additional dimensions
and domains. These include resource mobilization
(in other words, the “revenue side” of the budget),
to a “progressive extension to the medium- to long-
term implications and risks,” and to an expansion
“to all levels of government and the broader public
sector, including state enterprises and public-
private partnerships” (Cangiano et al., 2013b, pp.
1-2). Heightened attention to scal risks, scal
transparency, and whole-of-government scal
activity—especially following the global nancial
crisis—has been a major driver of this expanding
scope (IMF, 2018b).
The economic functions of PFM have been
less prominent over the past two decades,
especially outside of OECD countries. The
classic public nance literature is clear about their
centrality. Public nance policy is about the role
of government in the economy and classically
covers the objectives of allocation, distribution,
and stabilization (Musgrave & Musgrave,
1989). Budget policy in the form of revenue and
expenditure policies, and broader scal policy
including public debt and surplus/decit levels,
both concern the choices and actions taken by
government in pursuit of these objectives.
In considering the expansion and updating of
the standard PFM objectives, it may be useful to
step back and consider the objectives of public
nance more broadly. Public nance objectives
are classically dened in another set of three:
“The provision for social goods, or the process
by which total resource use is divided between
private and social goods and by which the mix
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
23
of social goods is chosen. This provision may be
termed the allocation function of budget policy.
Adjustment of the distribution of income and
wealth to ensure conformance with what society
considers a ‘fair or ‘just’ state of distribution,
here referred to as the distribution function.
The use of budget policy as a means of
maintaining high employment, a reasonable
degree of price level stability, and an appropriate
rate of economic growth, with allowances
for effects on trade and on the balance of
payments. We refer to all these objectives as the
stabilization function” (Musgrave & Musgrave,
1989, p. 6).
The three public nance policy objectives, like
the trinity of objectives in the PFM literature,
reect the times in which they were developed.
The notions of allocation, distribution, and
stabilization come from a time that emphasized
government’s ability and duty to implement
policy in the light of “community values,”
including fairness (Case, 2008). This formulation
is arguably also now incomplete as a set of
objectives. While the institutional perspective
omits consideration of distribution, fairness, and
accountability, the economic perspective on public
nance omits reference to management processes
and how services are delivered (Annex G). It is
important to note, however, that the expansion of
PFM objectives to include service delivery is still
relatively recent, as “budgeting has become more
intimately linked with other processes—planning,
operational management, and performance
management” (Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2018, p. 78).
The contribution of PFM processes to service
delivery is acknowledged to be more modest and
less direct than to scal discipline, for example,
owing to the role of other processes such as human
resources management (World Bank, 1998).
Reassessing the PFM objectives for
the 2020s
The trinity of PFM objectives has stood
the test of time impressively well. Certainly,
neither aggregate scal discipline, nor allocative
efciency, nor operational efciency seems a
candidate for retirement as an objective. The
question is whether some expansion and change in
emphasis would better equip the objectives for the
demands of the coming decade. Although it may
seem a big step to suggest that these time-honored
objectives might be changed, the general principle
that such objectives should be dynamic and able to
respond to contemporary challenges, rather than
static and immutable, seems unobjectionable.
The standard PFM objectives have three
apparent limitations:
First, they may not adequately address all policy
considerations:
o The standard objectives are usually taken to
suggest by their ordering a hierarchy, with
scal discipline as foremost. That objective
dominates as a priority and drives the
sequencing of measures to strengthen the
PFM system.
o Fiscal discipline has become closely
associated, or even synonymous, with scal
tightening rather than allowing for a broader
interpretation of maintaining a sustainable
scal position to support macroeconomic
stability and growth.
33
o They exclude one of the three classic public
nance objectives, which is concerned
with the distribution of income and wealth.
While this could, in principle, be treated as
an implicit consideration through allocative
efciency, it typically is not the case.
o There is a fulsome treatment of allocative
efciency, but in practice the emphasis on
reallocation is insufcient and incremental
adjustments are the norm. A focus on
strategic reprioritization is missing.
Second, they may not cover sufciently all
institutional domains:
o The focus is limited to core expenditure
management. The objectives do not include
wider concerns, such as resource mobilization
24
and the revenue side of PFM, the wider public
sector beyond general government, and scal
risks over the medium to long term.
o They do not cover the delivery choices facing
government for the provision of collective
goods and services. Strategic allocation of
resources decides the level of budgetary
provision, but not the mode of provision.
o They do not consider the accessibility and
quality of public service delivery. Efciency
and cost effectiveness, as covered by
operational efciency, are necessary but
insufcient dimensions in the provision of
collective goods and services.
Third, they may not be explicit enough about
democratic accountability:
o They do not address the oversight and
accountability purpose of PFM in ensuring
proper scrutiny of the use of public
sector resources. There is no reference to
democratic accountability through the role
of legislatures or public participation to build
state legitimacy.
This report takes the position that the standard
PFM objectives would benet from some
expansion to address the observed limitations.
The insights of Musgrave and Musgrave (1989)
suggest how the objectives might better reect
scal policy objectives, and Cangiano et al.
(2013b) offer an example of how they might be
extended into other institutional domains. Table
2 sketches out how these perspectives suggest
expanding PFM objectives: broadening the policy
objectives to address risk; responding to the need
for major policy change and reprioritization;
broadening the institutional coverage to include
modes of delivery; and adding policy objectives
concerning stability, fairness, and accountability.
Table 2: Refreshing the PFM objectives – proposals for discussion
Standard PFM objecves or “desirable
budgetary outcomes” (oen treated in
pracce as hierarchical or sequenal)
Nature of proposed
update and
expansion
Updated PFM objecves (no assumed hierarchy
or sequence; focus on the overall balance and
trade-os)
AggregateFiscalDiscipline:Budget
totalsshouldbetheresultofexplicit,
enforceddecisions;theyshould
notmerelyaccommodatespending
demands.Thesetotalsshouldbeset
beforeindividualspendingdecisionsare
made,andshouldbesustainableover
themediumtermandbeyond.
Broaden policy
objecves
concerning risk
Fiscal Discipline and Managed Risk:Budget
totalsshouldbetheresultofexplicit,enforced
decisions;theyshouldnotmerelyaccommodate
spendingdemands.Thesetotalsshouldbeset
beforeindividualspendingdecisionsaremade,
and debt and decit levelsshouldbesustainable
overthemediumtermandbeyond.Medium-
term scal risks across the enre public sector
should be assessed and managed.
AllocaveEciency(orstrategic
allocaonofresources):Expenditures
shouldbebasedongovernment
prioriesandontheeecvenessof
publicprograms.Thebudgetsystem
shouldspurreallocaonfromlesserto
higherprioriesandfromlesstomore
eecveprograms.
Broaden policy
objecves
concerning change
Allocave Eciency and Strategic
Repriorizaon: Revenue and expenditure
policiesshouldbebasedongovernment
prioriesandontheeecvenessofpublic
programs.Thescalsystemshouldspur
reallocaonfromlessertohigherprioriesand
fromlesstomoreeecveprogramsacross
the public sector, with the capability to manage
fundamental policy change.
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
25
Standard PFM objecves or “desirable
budgetary outcomes” (oen treated in
pracce as hierarchical or sequenal)
Nature of proposed
update and
expansion
Updated PFM objecves (no assumed hierarchy
or sequence; focus on the overall balance and
trade-os)
OperaonalEciency(orecient
servicedelivery):Agenciesshould
producegoodsandservicesatacost
thatachievesongoingeciencygains
and(totheextentappropriate)is
compevewithmarketprices.
Broaden
instuonal
coverage to include
modes of delivery
OperaonalEciencyand Service Quality:
Government should providegoodsandservices
atacostthatachievesongoingeciencygains
and(totheextentappropriate)iscompeve
withmarketprices.It should use modes of
delivery that opmize service quality and
ensure accessibility.
Add policy
objecves
concerning stability
Macroeconomic Stability: Fiscal policies should
support high employment and price level
stability, and an appropriate rate of economic
growth, with allowances for eects on trade
and on the balance of payments. Trade-os with
other socioeconomic objecves should explicitly
inform scal decisions.
Add policy
objecves
concerning fairness
Fairness and Legimacy: Budget policy choices
should produce a distribuon of income and
wealth that conforms to what society considers
a “fair” or “just” state of distribuon. There
should be sucient transparency, parcipaon,
and accountability for the public to be sased
of the legimacy of processes and decisions.
Add policy
objecves
concerning
accountability
Democrac Accountability: The exercise
and manner of raising revenues and of
allocang, execung, and accounng for
expenditures should contribute to condence
in the capabilies and discreon of the state.
These processes and rounes, appropriately
conducted, should build and sustain capable and
accountable instuons.
*FromCamposandPradhan(1996);PEFASecretariat(2016);Schick(1998a);andWorldBank(1998).Schickformulaon
usedhere.
*DrawingonWorkingGroupdeliberaonsandconsultaons,andliteratureincludingAllen,Hemming,andPoer(2013);
Andrewsetal.(2014);Cangianoetal.(2013b);Cangiano,Gelb,andGoodwin-Groen(2019);deRenzio(2009);Diamond(2013);
Hughes(2018);andMusgraveandMusgrave(1989).
Note:ItalicizedwordsinthenalcolumnmarkchangesoraddionstothelanguageofthestandardPFMobjecves.
Source:Authors’formulaon,drawingonliteraturecitedabove.
Expanding the roster of PFM objectives as
proposed here will inevitably increase the
probability of conict among them. Normative
tensions emerge when considering emphasizing
one objective over another or when pursuing
several in conjunction. While conicts in policy
design are not in fact new (Musgrave & Musgrave,
1989), they have been somewhat submerged or
obscured by the standard PFM objectives. One
consequence of the expansion proposed here is to
restore a political dimension to the consideration
of objectives. While no position is taken in
this report about their relative merits, Chapter
4 explores some of the tensions and potential
trade-offs—especially between stabilization and
distribution. It is a fundamental task of democratic
politics to resolve these normative conicts over
socioeconomic objectives in ways that advance
the overall goals of government.
26
Moving on from here
This chapter has reviewed the assumptions
inherent in the current approach to
strengthening PFM in development. Put
broadly, the story comprises two strands. First,
the assumptions draw from a set of conventions
concerning the desired operational performance
of PFM processes. This approach underpins
the growing professional “discipline” of PFM
specialists within development agencies,
consulting rms, universities, and think
tanks, or working as independent consultants.
Second, these conventions are seen as the path
to achieving a standard set of PFM objectives
representing a universal statement of the purposes
of strengthening PFM and implicitly prioritizing
scal discipline.
These assumptions represent a “closed”
model for diagnosing shortcomings in the
operational performance of PFM processes
and for developing reform measures to
address those shortcomings. Within this model,
political and contextual variables are important in
understanding reform tactics and sequencing, but
wider considerations about the impact of PFM
processes on public policy, service delivery, and
development outcomes such as citizen well-being
are not major variables in determining desirable
institutional arrangements. The next chapter
examines the inuence and results of this “closed”
model and proposes some ways to build on its
demonstrated strengths.
Chapter 2: Managing Public Finance
A Reappraisal
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
27
This chapter builds on the signicant body
of practitioner and academic work that has
constructed and reviewed the dominant
current approach to strengthening PFM in
development. That work has usefully set out
the assumed trinity of standard objectives in
PFM and the set of public sector institutional
arrangements and processes that are thought to
strongly inuence the achievement, or not, of
those objectives. As the previous chapter noted,
these assumptions represent a “closed” model
for diagnosing shortcomings in the operational
performance of PFM processes and for developing
reform measures. This chapter considers the utility
of the conventional model and proposes some
ways to build on its strengths in order to improve
the effectiveness of external technical advice. It
addresses two of the problems that were identied
and discussed in the introductory chapter. First,
the pace of learning about how external assistance
can better support improvements in PFM is too
slow. Second, development agencies’ preference
for following a common approach has reduced
opportunities to test ideas through competition.
Faster learning about external
support for PFM
More and better evidence about PFM support
interventions is needed to accelerate learning
about the effectiveness of external technical
advice. Knowledge and learning about the role
and use of PFM conventions in external support
and the evidence of impact both fall short of what
is required to drive real improvements. Within
the “closed” model, the rst question is what
would enable faster learning about how external
assistance can better support improvements
in PFM.
PFM conventions as a route map for
external support
Assessing progress in strengthening PFM is
tough. The sheer complexity of managing public
nance makes analysis difcult, as it is an area
of signicant “causal density” characterized
by “high uncertainty, which is a function of
the numerous pathways and feedback loops
connecting inputs, actions and outcomes, the
entity’s openness to exogenous inuences, and
the capacity of constituent elements (most notably
people) to exercise discretion” (Woolcock, 2013,
p. 8). Most public sector systems are a bewildering
mix of cause and effect in relation to any results
achieved. Finding a way of breaking this down
into manageable pieces, however imperfect, is in
itself a notable accomplishment (Simson, Sharma
& Aziz, 2011). In this respect, the PFM discipline
has been enormously successful at imposing
some simplied order on the conceptual territory
of interventions, institutional reforms, and
intermediate PFM results. The degree to which
this conceptual simplication has enabled real-
world development results is less clear, however.
Conceptual simplication has permitted a
focused discussion about institutional reforms.
The public sector results chain is long and open to
so many inuences that the relative signicance
of each one cannot be assessed. In consequence,
a model for examining public sector results that
attempts to consider all of the relevant inuences
and variables provides domestic reformers and
providers of external support with little practical
guidance to be applied in context. As discussed
in Chapter 2, the response of the PFM discipline
has been to collate and standardize the observed
features of effective operational performance
in PFM processes into a set of conventions that
describe an “effective” PFM system (Simson et
al., 2011). For example, the convention regarding
performance evaluation for service delivery, as
set out in the PEFA framework as the targeted
performance standard, is that “independent
evaluations of the efciency and effectiveness
of service delivery have been carried out and
published for most ministries at least once within
the last three years” (PEFA Secretariat, 2016, p.
3. BUILDING ON THE STRENGTHS OF THE “CLOSED” PFM MODEL
28
28). Here the test is not whether evaluations are
used in practice to improve service delivery—
or other outcomes that relate to the standard
PFM objectives of scal discipline, allocative
efciency, and operational efciency. The test
instead focuses on the degree of conformity with a
general standard.
Identifying conformity with conventions as the
stepping stone to results and as the proximate
target for external interventions reduces the
number of confounding factors in play. It
offers a shorter and more tractable model of the
public sector results chain. The fault lines in this
simplication are well-recognized, however.
The conventions are not as well-known, as
xed, or indeed as proven to be central to results
as the model suggests. Arguably, removing
consideration of many external political, social,
cultural, and context-specic inuences on the
achievement of results is to move in exactly the
wrong direction.
1
There is a risk of rendering
PFM as a technocratic domain and disregarding
crucial non-technical drivers of reform (Fritz et
al., 2017). Having said that, many PFM experts
see value in this simplifying archetype. Although
there are signicant limitations and risks in this
“closed” conceptualization (Schick, 2019), its
ability to make a complex territory legible is
clear. Moreover, despite offering little help in
interpreting the signicance of context, it has led
to a culture of inquiry within the PFM discipline
about the nature of institutional arrangements for
PFM and their place in achieving results.
It is sometimes suggested that the development
of PFM assessment frameworks containing
conventions for operational performance in
PFM may encourage gaming (Hadley & Miller,
2016; Krause et al., 2014). Gaming refers in a
strict sense either to strategic, self-interested
manipulation of the scales or criteria used for
measurement (such as selecting the indicators
that give the preferred results) or to manipulation
of the data resulting from those measurements
(Courty & Marschke, 2004; Hood, 2006; Van
Dooren et al., 2006).
2
In the case of standard
PFM assessments, incentives for gaming may be
attenuated, as the nancial rewards for conformity
with the conventions are not particularly high
and there is considerable transparency within the
frameworks about how the ratings are calculated.
3
The risk of gaming cannot be entirely disregarded,
however, especially with respect to the replication
or imitation of formal PFM processes in relation to
disbursement triggers for development assistance.
Limited knowledge and the slow pace
of learning
The record of evidence and results is hard
to decipher
Measuring the impact of technical advice on
strengthening PFM is a difcult task. There is
surprisingly little to be concluded from research
concerning the effectiveness of development
assistance in improving PFM. In principle,
research might look at evidence that external
interventions can have a causal role in improving
conformity with PFM conventions or that
strengthening the conventions can be necessary
for achieving development results. The case may
even be made that PFM interventions can in some
other way have a directly causal role in achieving
development results. Given this high “causal
density,” it is important also to look from the other
end of the public sector results chain, identifying
observed improvements and scanning the horizon
of possibilities in considering what caused them.
Annex H offers a partial summary of the literature
reviewed for this report and provides some
representative research summaries.
Recent analyses of the evaluation literature
note that the evidence base concerning the
impact of PFM support is patchy at best (De
Lay, Mills, Jadeja & Lucas, 2015; de Renzio,
Andrews & Mills, 2010; Mills, 2018; Pretorius &
Pretorius, 2009). A major evaluation of “Public
Finance for Development” being undertaken by
the World Bank’s Independent Evaluation Group
(IEG) includes support for PFM. It will assess
whether the design and implementation of World
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
29
Bank interventions have contributed to better
PFM outcomes—both intermediate outcomes,
such as improved predictability and control in
budget execution, and nal outcomes, such as the
achievement of a strategic allocation of resources
(IEG, 2018).
The current state of knowledge about the impact
of external PFM support can be summarized as
follows. There is some, distinctly limited, evidence
that donor interventions—such as investment
projects or technical assistance missions—can lead
to improved conformity with PFM conventions.
For example, in examining a number of case
studies, Orth, Schmitt, Krisch, and Oltsch (2017)
found that budget support (comprising funding
through government systems, conditionality,
policy dialogue, and technical assistance) was
associated with increased government spending in
social sectors, stronger PFM, and less corruption.
There is perhaps more compelling evidence
that interventions can lead to improved results
by linking resource allocation more directly to
policy intentions and by improving transparency,
but the evidence points toward participation and
consultation as the drivers of these improvements
more than institutional reforms (De Lay et al.,
2015). Finally, there is some limited evidence
that, however it is achieved, conformity with
the conventions can improve scal and service
delivery results. For example, Welham et al. (2017)
nd that better public nancial management,
as measured by PEFA, is associated with lower
variance in overall budget execution rates and
improved health outcomes. But there are many
identied cases in which there is seemingly no
connection.
The same challenges affect assessments that
look back up the results chains to detect
the contribution of external PFM support.
Evaluations that look back from improved
development results at the national or sector
level and ask whether these are attributable
to donor interventions in PFM have largely
drawn a blank—whether these concern general
develop-ment progress, as measured by economic
growth and poverty reduction (Radelet, 2015),
or improvements in the health sector (Morrison,
2013). Similarly, evaluations have not shown that
improved development results can be attributed
to improvements in PEFA ratings, for example.
When there has been an identied improvement
in country PEFA ratings, implying improved
conformity with the PFM conventions, this has
rarely been attributable to donor interventions
(Lawson, 2012).
The pace of learning remains frustratingly
slow
The challenges of evaluation in PFM echo those
faced by social science research more broadly.
Empirical work on public sector management and,
within it, PFM offers just one particular case of
a larger difculty. The denitional challenges in
capturing institutional changes and measuring
results are enormous. The hunt for quasi-
scientic “single treatments” that might lead to
specic results is undoubtedly misplaced. With
so many contextual factors in play, the attribution
issues are confounding. The time lags between
interventions and effects are outside the scope
of most available data. Controlled experiments
are seldom feasible, and natural experiments are
rare.
4
PFM, at least, is a domain in which at least
some of the measurement challenges have been
addressed, particularly in relation to assessing
conformity with conventions and with scal
results (Schick, 1998a). Nonetheless, there has
been disappointment that empirical ndings have
not emerged more rapidly. PFM interventions may
be good enough, but they could still be better. The
question is how to achieve that.
There have been some promising ideas about
how to accelerate improvements in knowledge
about PFM support, but no breakthroughs. The
question of how to embed political and contextual
considerations in technical analyses has been the
subject of intense debate in recent years (Annex
I). Ideas about “adaptive management,” “doing
development differently,” and “thinking and
working politically” in governance reforms have
30
become increasingly sophisticated (Andrews,
2012; Green, 2018; Teskey & Tyrrel, 2017) but
show some clear similarity to ideas from the early
1990s (Berg, 1993). Similarly, deliberations about
optimal PFM reform sequencing have found little
to agree on beyond an entrenched assertion that
basic disciplines matter (Diamond, 2012; Fritz,
Hedger & Lopes, 2011; USAID, 2014).
5
The
practical result has been a series of relatively
distinct ideas about supporting and sequencing
institutional change. Each one has seemingly been
clear and self-standing until the next one arrives
(Pretorius & Pretorius, 2009) (Annex J).
Some ways forward: better data
collection and knowledge sharing
If better and faster learning is the goal, then
action is needed on the part of both individual
agencies and the wider PFM discipline.
Individual agencies can make a difference, such
as when the World Bank acted as a catalyst for
research on economic growth in the 1990s.
That example showed that detailed tracking
of country-level institutional reforms through
high-quality case studies, coupled with greater
experimentation with impact evaluations (in the
occasional cases when “natural experiments” can
be found), can be a useful contribution. But the
biggest gains could come from mobilizing the
PFM discipline as a whole. If assistance providers
and client governments had stronger incentives
to release information about interventions and
results using standardized metrics—moving
away from the current situation, in which most
relevant knowledge remains tacit and unshared—
then richer and more powerful analysis could be
brought to bear.
One key to progress lies in moving beyond the
current fragmentation among agency-specic
research and evaluation initiatives and data
sharing. Open-source data on public sector
institutional change could spur both external
research and internal learning, supporting the
development of a secondary industry of analysis
of project data. Alongside the IMF, multilateral
development banks (MDBs) are the most signicant
providers of technical advice and funding for
PFM (Simson et al., 2011). However, the track
record of deep collaboration among international
organizations is not encouraging, as they each
maintain separate analytical and knowledge
functions. “There are only a few examples
where MDBs have worked together and taken
advantage of the capabilities in sister institutions.
More commonly, they operate independently.
For example, each MDB has its own research
department and independent evaluation ofce.
They each develop individual country strategies.
They have their own assessment frameworks
for development effectiveness” (Bhattacharya,
Kharas, Plant & Prizzon, 2018, pp. 11–12). The
coordination of data collection in other areas
suggests that progress in knowledge sharing across
agencies is likely to take the form of agreement
on principles and classications accompanied by
persistent small steps in the right direction, rather
than a major breakthrough (Inter-Agency Group
on Economic and Financial Statistics, 2019). Two
ideas may hold some promise.
Developing new standards for data collection
and sharing
Proposal 1: Assess offers of technical
advice against standards for the provision
of information and evidence justifying the
approach and for the planned dissemination of
data about impact
One potential way forward is the use of a
standardized framework for data collection
and sharing. Current strategies for learning about
the effectiveness of development interventions are
of limited utility in the face of provider agencies’
incentives to restrict information about their
activities and to make excessive claims about their
impact, and of client governments’ incentives
not to challenge that behavior. Exposing more
clearly the basis on which offers of technical
advice are made and the claims that they entail
could initiate a virtuous circle. Governments
would have a basis for making more informed
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
31
choices among providers of technical advice and
potential approaches, and providers of technical
advice would have greater incentive to share
data and justify claims. Such a framework could
include standardized data categories to allow for
comparison among design options and among
results achieved.
Assessing how well the operational performance
of PFM processes conforms to PFM conventions
follows a well-established pattern of using
standard frameworks to design external
interventions (World Bank, 2010). The PFM
discipline could develop a tool to assess how well
PFM support interventions conform to open data
standards on program design and results. Such a
tool would ask how clearly the proposals developed
by technical advice providers are elaborated along
two dimensions. First, an efciency justication
dimension would rate proposals according to the
degree to which they show the potential costs
involved, such as nancial and transactional
costs, and the likely returns. Second, an empirical
justication dimension would rate proposals on
the availability of evidence on which they draw
to make their case. Development of this tool could
draw from cross-country and multisector studies
about how this type of reform proposal has worked
out in general, and from impact evaluations or
other research that can test for the salience of
distinctive contextual conditions.
The data assessment tool could be used as
part of “quality at entry” processes within
international agencies. While the tool would
assess the transparency with which project
proposals are justied nancially and empirically,
it would not be used to collect actual project data.
Use of the tool could be combined with some
form of independent, non-binding review or
validation—possibly by an arm’s-length agency
or entity of some form—that the appropriate
procedures for using the assessment tool had been
followed. The “PEFA Check” provided by the
PEFA Secretariat is one such example.
6
The results measurement component could spur
a much-needed step-change in measuring the
results achieved through complex institutional
reforms, including how to treat different types
of evidence (Bates & Glennerster, 2017; Pritchett
& Sandefur, 2013). The current “publish what you
fund” movement is of value for input coordination.
Here, though, we propose a new “reveal what
you are proposing and what you did” movement,
which would be of greater value in enriching the
PFM discipline with more solid evidence about
successes and failures, perhaps supporting client
governments through access to greater choice
among different technical advice options.
The pressure to publish standard data
might prompt innovations in the means of
data collection and stronger leadership by
international organizations. Developments such
as algorithmic learning and cell phone surveys
could emerge as mechanisms for collating expert
assessments and amassing data on implementation
and results. While the hope may be overblown
that “big data” might rapidly nd meaning within
a mass of metrics about reforms, results, and
contexts (Lazer, Kennedy, King & Vespignani,
2014), some large-scale data collection approaches
could help to indicate which avenues to explore
further (Calvard, 2016). Ofcial fora such as the
OECD DAC and the United Nations Department
of Economic and Social Affairs (UNDESA) might
shift their focus toward assessing whether advice
providers and client governments are willing to
open up their reform approaches to contribute to
the global data pool.
Lowering risk in sharing project shortcomings
Proposal 2: Establish practitioner groups
to share sensitive performance information
on PFM interventions on a voluntary and
condential basis to identify ways of improving
performance
A complementary approach may be to open up
a smaller dataset for more in-depth review and
lesson sharing. Robust and comparable external
measurement of results can seem risky for providers
32
of technical advice that need to make claims
about the benets of their interventions. Provider
agencies face strong incentives to demonstrate to
their shareholders or funders that they are highly
effective, which means that rigorous, veriable,
and comparable measurement of results by third
parties may not be a high priority (Barder, 2009).
Political pressures on provider agencies instead
emphasize the need to demonstrate visible, short-
term results to shareholders, taxpayers, or other
principals (Gulrajani, 2017; Honig, 2018; Koch
et al., 2017; Power, Scheytt, Soin & Sahlin,
2009; Valters & Whitty, 2017). Risk aversion is
especially high among providers in fragile states
(Dendura & Flynn, 2011; McKechnie & Davies,
2013). Open data, deep knowledge, and sharing of
learning are not likely to be the primary concern.
In some other sectors in OECD countries, these
concerns have been addressed through the
creation of “data clubs,” or private networks
for sharing sensitive data, which operate
along reciprocal lines. This approach could be
considered for the PFM sector as well. Submission
of a base set of data and the commitment by all
participants to treating all data shared in strict
condentiality would be conditions of joining a
PFM data club. Such an approach has been shown
to overcome government concerns and to facilitate
the sharing of sensitive safety data concerning
large city subway systems (Hood, Dixon, &
Wilson, 2009; Wilson, 2010) as well as potentially
damaging information on school performance
(Glaister & Anderson, 2005). Membership would
provide access to an aggregate, anonymized
summary of the data that have been shared by
others, and would allow individual members to
approach each other for more tailored sharing of
information. Club membership could be offered
to entities or individuals, whether from client
governments, international organizations, or
donors and other assistance providers. Opting into
the club would entail careful specication of the
parties or types of parties with whom the data may
be shared as well as whether and when the data
must be anonymized (Glaister & Anderson, 2005).
New advances in blockchain technology could
offer a mechanism for permitting secure sharing
of sensitive information within an approved group
of disparate participants among whom trust needs
to be established (Reinsberg, 2018).
Members, serving as representatives of their
respective agencies, would thus be able to
obtain authoritative technical support and
data and have the credibility to speak critically
about their agency’s approach. They would
decide which data mattered and how to obtain
information for sharing, with an emphasis on
practical and implementable actions and explicit
protocols about how the data could be used in their
respective agencies. Members would establish the
governance arrangements for the club. Agencies
would be able to opt out of the club at any
time, with all references to their data removed
(Anderson, 2005; Glaister & Anderson, 2005;
Hood et al., 2009; Wildy, 2004; Wilson, 2010).
An important distinction is that these
condential data clubs are not peer learning
exercises. Peer learning focuses on the individual
and is intended to contribute to individual-level
gains in knowledge and insights—although with a
view to their making impacts at the organizational,
sector, or national level (Andrews & Manning,
2015). The Collaborative Africa Budget Reform
Initiative (CABRI), the Public Expenditure
Management Network in Asia (PEMNA), and the
Public Expenditure Management Peer Assisted
Learning (PEMPAL) network for the Europe and
Central Asia region are examples of successful
initiatives in the peer group mold (PEMPAL
Steering Committee, 2012; World Bank, 2013).
By contrast, data clubs are intended to provide
insights at the system-wide level.
Contestation and choice in
PFM advice
The growing diversity in providers of
development assistance and the increased
choice experienced by some governments
could strengthen the market for technical
advice. Despite concerted efforts over 15 years
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
33
to improve donor coordination, success continues
to be limited and sporadic. There may be some
conditions under which greater competition would
be a desirable or even superior approach. This
section explores that possibility with regard to
technical advice on strengthening PFM. It builds
on the consensus of the “closed” PFM model
regarding the operational performance of PFM
processes needed to achieve the trinity of standard
PFM objectives. The core question is whether
greater contestation among intervention ideas and
options, and greater government choice over those
options, could help to improve innovation and
results in external assistance for PFM.
Donor coordination and its
emerging limits
Rationale and future prospects
Effective coordination among donors in the
provision of development assistance has long
been stated as an important principle and
objective. Coordination is pursued primarily to
maximize the impact of development nancing,
either by reducing unintended overlaps in
interventions (Barder, Gavas, Maxwell & Johnson,
2010) or by encouraging compliance with a larger
technical agenda or set of standards determined by
the international community. Harmonization and
alignment of international aid were central features
of the 2005 Paris Declaration and its successor
agreements. The “Strengthened Approach to
Public Financial Management” was put forward
as a common technical agenda and made a strong
case for coordination as part of the PEFA program
(OECD DAC, 2003). Coordination with reference
to a technical agenda was given extra force by the
concern that independent actions by development
agencies “may postpone necessary adjustment
because there is so little conditionality” (Woods,
2008, p. 1207) and so could be wasteful (Klein
& Harford, 2005, p. 3). The arguments for
coordination are bolstered by a transaction
costs argument that fragmented external support
can further burden already overloaded client
governments.
There is a contrary case to be made that
coordination may not always be desirable
or realistic. Coordination, in the sense of
compliance with a common set of assumptions
about technical approaches, seeks by denition to
reduce experimentation and choice. It locks in the
presumption that adherence to current conventions
is the right way to go (Scharfstein & Stein, 1990).
Separately, and regardless of whether coordination
can in principle achieve the aim of more
effective development assistance, there is a more
pragmatic argument that preaching coordination
can be unrealistic, as it is often not delivered in
practice. Despite concerted efforts and a series of
global commitments, the evidence suggests that
coordination efforts have been only moderately
successful. Many attempts at coordination have
failed to impose a rational division of labor among
donors based on comparative advantage (CABRI,
2014; Brookings Institution and CGD, 2011)
because there is no effective “umpire” to impose
discipline (Harris, 2011).
Recent research is pessimistic about the
prospects for improved donor coordination at
a general level in development cooperation.
Incentives to disregard coordination include
the need to pursue the national interests of the
donor country even at the expense of greater
transaction costs, and the need to appease interests
in partner countries in order to maintain a longer-
term relationship (Bourguignon & Platteau,
2015; Olivié & Pérez, 2016). The increase in aid
impact evaluations and the growing prominence
of indices comparing donor performance are
contributing to increased fragmentation, as
these metrics inherently promote competition
among development agencies. Thus, at least
according to some analysts, “efforts to improve
donor coordination are doomed to failure, ‘cheap
talk’, since they do not change the incentives
underlying donors’ strategic interaction” (Annen
& Moers, 2012, p. 30). Although the reality may
be somewhere in between, the track record of
effective coordination without corresponding
change in incentives is not strong.
34
Structural changes in the supply of
development assistance
Coordination is likely to become more
challenging as new sources of development
nance create greater choice for client
governments. As countries move into middle-
income status and the landscape of development
nance diversies to include new players, the
traditional model of coordination is coming
under strain (Greenhill et al., 2013; Prizzon,
2014; Schmaljohann & Prizzon, 2014). Recent
evidence shows signicant heterogeneity among
a growing group of non-DAC providers of
development cooperation (Lauria & Fumagalli,
2019). This trend suggests that client governments
may gain access to greater and more meaningful
choices among all donors, rather than merely a
binary distinction between DAC and non-DAC
alternatives. Well-established major funders and
advice providers appear to be relinquishing some
of their ownership of and inuence on PFM
advice in the face of alternative development
nance sources—most notably China, but also
Turkey, the Islamic Development Bank, and other
“new donors” (Greenhill et al., 2013; Hanauer
& Morris, 2014).
7
China, in particular, brings a
corresponding increase in the volume of public
management technical assistance embedded
within projects—especially infrastructure
initiatives (Lum, 2009). The product being offered
may also vary with the type of provider. Such
products could range from the explicit provision
of technical advice by development agency staff
to assist in the implementation of an institutional
reform agenda, to implicit or informal advice
associated with large infrastructure nancing on
near-market terms, to advice provided by a major
consulting rm working under contract on a full
cost-recovery basis.
New sources of technical advice may further
increase the degree of country choice. The
proliferation of small interventions (Fengler &
Kharas, 2010), combined with a growing diversity
of assistance providers, are allowing countries such
as Ethiopia, Rwanda, and Sierra Leone to exercise
greater choice in selecting preferred providers of
technical advice.
8
There are signs that a growing
number of “challenger agencies” are emerging,
offering advice without funding and espousing
innovative methods or ideas.
9
Typically these
organizations are small, non-governmental, non-
prot, and independently funded, often connected
to policy think tanks, research institutes, or
universities. These agencies tend to be proponents
of problem-based and adaptive approaches to PFM
support, and they appear less likely to be bound
by the prescriptive inuence of the conventions or
incentives of the PFM discipline. They often work
directly for client governments, rather than merely
with those governments at the behest of other
organizations such as donors and IFIs.
The improbability of achieving a market-
based approach at scale
Donor aversion and demand-side constraints
A more open and competitive market for
technical advice in development is often
invoked and has long been predicted by some
commentators (Barder, 2009; de Renzio &
Rogerson, 2005; O’Keefe, 2007).
10
A full market
would be characterized by many buyers and
sellers, distinct products, low barriers to supplier
entry and exit, and robust information about prices.
Those features largely do not apply in the case of
technical advice for lower-income countries on
PFM (or indeed on other technical development
concerns). Although there is often, de facto,
considerable competition among development
agencies for projects and inuence at the country
level, the strength of the coordination paradigm
makes explicit consideration of competition in
development assistance an awkward topic and a
contentious proposal.
11
It is also likely to be too
disruptive and costly to the integrated business
models of the IFIs, which bundle together their
functions of nancing and technical advice—
typically along with broader global public goods.
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
35
Decoupling of funding for technical advice
from the selection of providers would need
to be a central feature of a proper market. A
structural change of that type is highly improbable
at scale in the case of development assistance to
lower-income countries.
12
Any model in which
funders detach themselves from inuence over
the external providers of advice and assistance to
governments (Barder, 2009; Booth, 2013; Klein &
Harford, 2005) would remove the key device by
which donors provide assurance to their political
principals and their ultimate customers—namely,
domestic taxpayers in donor countries—that
their funds are well used (Booth, 2013; Klein &
Harford, 2005; Martens, 2005; Mosley, 1985).
Donors themselves would resist strongly, since
they “proceduralize” operations, imposing internal
steps and hurdles as a proxy for ensuring quality
in an environment where nal results are hard
to determine (Power et al., 2009). This is only
possible if the funder has some signicant control
over the type of advice that the disbursed funds are
used to purchase. In addition, since a signicant
proportion of donor nancing is ultimately used
to nance the donors’ own professional services
(Browne, 2012), there would be signicant
internal resistance.
13
Any serious debate about a market for
technical advice must also recognize that there
are signicant constraints on the demand side.
While governments in lower-income countries
may in principle seek to maximize the quality
of technical assistance, they are likely to be
as much or more concerned with maximizing
concessional nancial ows (Greenhill et al.,
2013; Prizzon, 2014; Schmaljohann & Prizzon,
2014).
14
Governments have mixed and multiple
motives when expressing demand. They may be
reluctant to express clear and reliable demand for
the external support they require when a wider
partnership and nancing agenda are at stake
(Khemani, 2017). Just like provider agencies,
client governments are inuenced by notions
of comparative good practice in other countries
and “cutting-edge” ideas and models, with the
corresponding temptation to choose based on
notions of modernity more than on effectiveness
(Lawson, 2012).
Possible evolution in the longer term
The market for technical advice in lower-
income countries will evolve over the longer
term in response to the inux of new sources
of nance and new providers of advice,
but current donors are likely to resist that
disruption. For the foreseeable future, OECD-
DAC donors and long-standing IFIs will continue
to provide the predominant share of concessional
nancing to lower-income countries, with the
notable exception of China in some cases. These
well-established actors have, in effect, formed a
cartel—both for the external funding of technical
advice, and for determining the providers and
often the content of that technical advice. This
syndrome is observed clearly in the funding and
provision of advice on PFM (AlphaBeta, 2018).
As discussed above, the business model, risk
management, and quality assurance pressures and
requirements faced by donors and IFIs make it
unlikely that they would yield a substantial degree
of choice to client governments about advice,
services, and even providers. The rise of new
sources of nancing and technical advice—for
example, from donors outside the OECD-DAC
or from foundations and non-prot actors—might
eventually start to reduce the dominance of some
long-standing donors and IFIs across all areas of
technical advice on PFM. However, the heads of
those agencies are unlikely to acquiesce to, or
to collaborate readily with, plans that would put
them at odds with the interests of their political
principals and, ultimately, with those of taxpayers
in donor countries (Mosley, 1985; Martens, 2005).
Donors and IFIs are likely also to argue that they
are the guardians of quality assurance and results
attainment when considering requests by client
governments for technical advice on PFM.
Middle-income countries are a different
case. More comprehensive competitive market
approaches are already emerging in middle-income
36
contexts, with both benecial and challenging
features. Those countries tend to be characterized
by some or all of the following features: greater
scal capacity to self-nance technical advice,
greater access to diversied sources of development
nance (including from international capital
markets), and a higher-capacity bureaucracy
with stronger commissioning acumen. In those
contexts, there is evidence of a wider array of
management consulting rms working directly
for governments. Following this trend, some IFIs
have started to offer technical advisory services
on a directly reimbursable basis, outside of the
main lending relationship (for example, the World
Bank’s Reimbursable Advisory Services), and the
IMF has been scaling up its program of regional
Technical Assistance Centers. The message,
therefore, is that competition is likely to emerge
naturally as countries develop economically—
provided that they are not aficted by conict—
but the transition is necessarily slow.
One way forward: managed options and
greater choice
Contestation of options, not competition
among providers
More active country choice in technical advice
is possible for lower-income countries in the
short and medium term, but the reality is that
funders will continue to manage that choice. The
strongest steps that provider agencies might take
are to develop a comparable range of intervention
options, all of which meet their quality standards,
and to provide a choice to governments among the
set of options that have been assessed and veried.
The essential distinction here is that the number or
diversity of credible providers of technical advice
ceases to be the main consideration, replaced
by the number and heterogeneity of credible
intervention options. This shifts the debate from
donor coordination versus donor competition
toward contestation among ideas. It could, in
principle, apply with equivalent effect to one
provider or many providers.
Choice mechanisms that use reputational
feedback on providers can help to identify
promising or proven types of interventions,
even when a fully competitive market is not
possible. The theoretical and empirical literature
on quasi-markets for public service delivery
in OECD countries shows that greater choice
and competition can lead to improvements in
innovation, diversication, and performance when
users are able to indicate preferences and use the
threat of exit (Le Grand, 2010; Le Grand, 2007;
Lubienski, 2009). Some commentators argue that
the basis for a market in development assistance
is already in place (O’Keefe, 2007),
15
since client
governments have at their disposal information
about the characteristics and performance of
assistance providers (de Renzio & Rogerson,
2005). It is further argued that existing competitive
procurement methods for selecting technical
assistance providers could be extended radically
through electronic auction formats in tendering
and better information about the reputation and
past performance of providers (Barder, 2009).
16
What these commentators are really pointing
to is the potential for greater government
choice to stimulate innovation and fresh ideas
and to improve the comparative assessment of
different intervention designs or variations in the
“intervention logic.”
17
Alternative options proposed by providers of
technical advice could each be analyzed based
on their proposed or implicit intervention
logic. Several overlapping questions are generally
considered explicitly or, more often, implicitly
in the design of external interventions and the
“theories of change” on which they rest.
18
One
question is the degree to which it is assumed that
the specied input (such as a training program
or new procedures) will lead in a linear fashion
to the intended output and outcome as set out in
a results chain (OECD, 2017), logframe (DFID,
2009; Team Technologies, 2005), or equivalent.
This approach is standard for most technical
assistance interventions. A second, contrasting
question concerns whether the theory of change
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
37
suggests uncertainty about the consequences
of any intervention and the need for exibility
and participation on the part of local actors
(Valters, 2015), thereby emphasizing the need
for iteration and adaptation. A third question is
whether incentives to achieve a specied outcome
could be combined with exibility concerning
the choice of input (Birdsall & Savedoff, 2010).
Examples of intervention types that follow a pure
outcome-based logic include “cash on delivery”
aid and development impact bonds. Finally, a
fourth question concerns the technical sequencing
of the proposed PFM content (Diamond, 2013),
including whether to strengthen “basic” or
foundational PFM processes rst. These four
questions underpin the variety of intervention
designs that can reasonably be proposed.
In practice, governments are typically offered
few meaningful choices when deciding which
PFM reforms to pursue and the intervention
logic that underpins the reform model. An
evaluation of external PFM interventions in
three African countries found that “government
authorities were presented with a limited range of
options…and were not encouraged either to consult
or to reect more widely on the choice of reform
models….There were apparently neither nancial
constraints nor political constraints determining
the choice of reform model, so we interpret this
as simply as a lack of adequate ideas: a policy
space constraint” (Lawson, 2012, p. 68, 72). The
absence of alternative ideas and propositions leads
to a corresponding lack of debate about different
reform options.
19
Despite the strengthening of
business case processes, quality-at-entry reviews,
and economic appraisal by many assistance
providers when it comes to project or program
design—including, in some cases, borrowing
from domestic options appraisal techniques
(HM Treasury, 2018)—it is evident from the
examination of development agency project
documentation that the alternatives considered
tend to be treated in a distinctly cursory way.
Projects typically propose one single, rst-best
intervention logic. In light of these challenges, the
Working Group proposes a potential way forward.
Piloting “managed choice” in external
PFM advice
Proposal 3: Experiment with “managed choice”
in the provision of technical advice, with a
coalition of funders and client governments
and the creation of a dedicated funding facility
In a “managed choice” model, providers of
PFM support would prepare more than one
intervention design option as the basis for
comparison, discussion, and—ultimately—
choice by the client government. Each option
would be subjected to a quality assurance process,
for example through robust peer review,
20
and
would explicitly harness available research
evidence. Offering multiple intervention options
is more expensive than asserting that there is just
one correct or superior way forward. However,
given the lack of certainty about what works and
the need for greater experimentation, it would be
a more honest and open-minded approach. When
offering options to a client government, any
differences in the intervention logic or technical
design would be emphasized and discussed openly.
Accordingly, each option would need to make
explicit the technical content and intervention
logic that underpinned it and the logical and
empirical justication for that approach.
The potential benets of this approach
stretch beyond creating more experiments to
assist in learning about what works in PFM
support interventions. Other benets could
include the incentives that such arrangements
would provide for strengthening relationships
among different parts of government as they
explore the implications of options together,
the increased motivation inherent in giving key
actors the opportunity to express their views and
inuence reform design, and the possibility that
the problems to be addressed would incorporate
locally identied issues more centrally. This
approach also brings risks, however, including
that preparing several options would increase
38
costs unreasonably and that government might be
unable to achieve a consensus choice—especially
if choices set up conicts along existing fault lines
within government.
While this proposal is still a long way from
creating a competitive market for PFM
support, it would move the PFM discipline
toward greater contestability of ideas. It may
not be known whether, for example, the IMF, the
World Bank, the United Kingdom’s Department
for International Development (DFID), or the
European Commission has the best track record
in supporting a particular dimension of PFM
reform. Equally, it may not be known what degree
of balance between standard technical design on
the one hand and problem-driven and adaptive
assistance on the other hand is likely to be most
effective. As noted in Annex H, the research
evidence is simply not good enough to provide
clear, denitive, or general answers. The benet
of introducing options and choices more strongly
into PFM support is that it would provide more
data to support choices among different types
of interventions and more information on which
approaches are most credible from the perspective
of the client government. It should also strengthen
the quality of the dialogue and relationships
between advice providers and client governments.
More vigorous and explicit contestation of the
ideas put forward by external advisers in their
engagement with government counterparts
would need to cover two facets. First, it must
entail a plurality of diverse viewpoints to
counterbalance the tendency of advisers to argue
for their own agency’s or their own discipline’s
position on PFM reform.
21
Second, it must shift the
incentives faced by external advisers so that they
can act in a more disinterested fashion. This would
mean that advice would not be unduly inuenced
by other objectives or agendas, such as a parallel
nancial relationship between the agency and the
government or an organizational predisposition
toward a particular approach or reform proposal
(in other words, a “house view”). While truly
disinterested advice may not be a realistic aim,
reducing conicting incentives and introducing
a mechanism for structured contestation of ideas
would be important steps in that direction (Annex
K).
This proposal would ideally be coupled
with improved availability and sharing of
information about the impact of external
interventions and projects (Proposal 1). Even
without much improvement in impact measures,
there is still a prima facie case for harnessing
the data and analysis that already exist. The
increased demand on the part of both technical
advice providers that are developing their options
and client governments that are assessing those
options for evidence of impact could itself drive
the requirement for more open and routine sharing
of assessments. So, while these two proposals
ought to be complementary, introducing choice
among options is still potentially worthwhile even
if better availability of impact measurement has
yet to emerge. In addition, donors that fund the
PFM advice provided by IFIs and consulting rms
could begin stipulating that the funded content
(such as manuals, guidance notes, and forecasting
models) be placed accessibly in the public
domain as a means of making PFM knowledge
more of a public good that is readily available to
governments.
A major consideration about feasibility is how
to create incentives for agencies to develop
alternative intervention designs and offer
genuine choices to governments. This approach
could harness the intellectual energy of those who
are hoping to see a more competitive approach to
technical advice for PFM. At the same time, it is
sufciently modest that it should be able to gain
acceptance among providers that might otherwise
be concerned about the loss of control implied by a
more open market and about the risks of detaching
advice from funding. The starting point is twofold:
appealing to PFM professionals’ desire to improve
their impact and, at the same time, encouraging a
couple of progressive donors to test the proposed
“managed choice” approach.
Chapter 3: Building on the Strengths of the “Closed” PFM Model
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
39
Consultations with bilateral PFM donors
suggest that some choice is implicit in dialogue
with client governments, but typically focuses on
the use of bilateral versus multilateral channels.
Some useful distinctions in the intervention design
and approach are revealed by choices among these
channels—for example, on issues such as the
approach to change management—and the client
government’s preference may be given some
weight in the decision. This is the case especially
when there is already a strong partnership between
the donor agency and the client government.
These are all positive steps in the direction
of “managed choice” and are supportive of a
partnership approach. However, there do not yet
appear to be instances of full implementation
of the proposal, as it is broadly set out here, to
experiment explicitly with “managed choice” in
the provision of technical advice. Further steps to
build on current practices could include making
more explicit the differences in intervention logic
when comparing two delivery channels, and for a
group of bilateral donors to request a multilateral
agency to pilot a “managed choice” approach as
part of granting them trust fund resources.
To bring more powerful incentives into
play, there would need to be a separate and
independent funding mechanism or facility.
With that established, options might include
giving a consortium of donor agencies access
to funds that would enable them to nance the
development and peer review of, for example,
three different approaches to improving PFM.
Alternatively, client governments could be given
a modest nancial incentive if they were able to
show that they had insisted upon the production,
scrutiny, and deliberation by PFM donors of a
credible choice of interventions. Most ambitious-
ly, an entirely separate funding mechanism could
create some degree of split between funding and
advice. A signicant test would be whether ofcial
donors or private foundations would be willing
to give third parties commissioning control over
such a technical advice fund.
Moving on from here
This chapter has proposed some ways to
build on the strengths of the current “closed”
model of strengthening PFM in development.
They respond to two problems identied in the
introductory chapter of this report: rst, that the
pace of learning about how external assistance
can better support improvements in PFM is too
slow, and second, that development agencies’
preference for following a common approach
has reduced opportunities to test ideas through
competition. The rst three International Working
Group proposals are as follows:
(1) Assess offers of technical advice against
standards for the provision of information and
evidence justifying the approach and for the
planned dissemination of data about impact;
(2) Establish practitioner groups to share sensitive
performance information on PFM interventions
on a voluntary and condential basis to identify
ways of improving performance; and
(3) Experiment with “managed choice” in the
provision of technical advice, with a coalition of
funders and client governments and the creation
of a dedicated funding facility.
The next chapter considers how to rethink
managing public nance as an “open” system
in which the inuences of PFM on government
policy choices, government actions (especially
service delivery), and development results are
the central focus. An effort to introduce more
real-world complexity into thinking about PFM
raises many questions. How can the conventions
that provide the benchmark for assessing the
operational performance of PFM processes
be used to investigate the links between PFM,
government actions, and development results?
How can PFM processes better support policy
change and become more responsive to a broader
set of socioeconomic objectives?
40
This chapter explores ways to rethink the
paradigm of PFM in international development
in order to reconnect it with public policy.
Refreshing and expanding the trinity of standard
PFM objectives would help to sharpen focus on
how PFM inuences government policy choices,
government actions, including service delivery,
and—ultimately—development results. Once the
complex trade-offs are apparent, PFM can work to
help policy makers address real-world priorities,
choices, and decisions (Schick, 2019).
This is difcult territory, as it begins to
depart from the concrete and “universalist”
assumptions of the “closed” model. Accordingly,
this chapter considers the potential for developing
a new generation of approaches to international
support for managing public nance that better
reect the real world. It addresses specically two
of the problems that were identied and discussed
in the introductory chapter. First, the ways in
which PFM matters for service delivery and for
sector outcomes are not well understood. “Service
delivery” is used in this chapter as an example of
a government action—a particularly important
action given the emphasis and priority attached to
public services by the international development
community. Second, the standard objectives and
conventions of PFM are not equipped to deal with
political choices and trade-offs or major policy
change, especially in the context of wide-ranging
and complex sets of government policy choices
and intended development results. (See Annex
B for a fuller discussion of the public policy
framework underpinning these concepts and their
interactions.)
Linking PFM to service delivery and
development results
There are clear linkages among levels of public
policy—namely, government policy choices,
government actions, and development results—
although the direction of causation is not easily
determined. Government policy choices concern
government intentions, as expressed through
statements and decisions about what it will
prioritize in principle and as revealed through its
actions. Public service delivery is one dimension
of government actions and outputs, concerning
specically the provision, commissioning,
or funding of collective goods and services.
Development results, as a subset of wider policy
impacts, are the outcomes related to government
choices and actions (Annex A; Annex B).
This chapter considers these issues in the
context of rethinking PFM as an “open” system.
Service delivery is considered rst as an example
of how PFM conventions relate to government
actions. Governments do much more than ensure
the delivery of services, but that particular task
clearly forms a crucial link between policy choices
and development results.
Understanding the link between PFM and
service delivery—as a means to improving
sector outcomes and other development
results—is a growing preoccupation for many
providers of development assistance. From this
agenda ows the general question of how PFM
conventions could be refreshed, harnessing better
evidence about the relevance and contribution
of specic PFM processes. Answering this will
require tools and techniques both to identify new
conventions and to manage the life cycle of existing
conventions. This effort should be accompanied
by a willingness to discard conventions that have
outlived their utility or their evidence base.
The dominance and the limits of PFM
conventions
The PFM conventions, discussed in Chapter
2, bring together lessons learned and the
tacit knowledge of practitioners to dene a
powerful and precise set of prescriptions. These
conventions are most readily observed in the wide
array—45 at current count—of PFM assessment
4. RETHINKING MANAGING PUBLIC FINANCE IN AN “OPEN” SYSTEM
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
41
frameworks that have been developed (PEFA
Secretariat, 2018), including most prominently
the PEFA methodology, TADAT, the Debt
Management Performance Assessment (DeMPA),
the Public Investment Management Assessment
(PIMA) tool, and the IMF’s Fiscal Transparency
Code (Annex F). Each framework is powered by
propositions about the “correct” conguration and
operational performance of PFM processes. For
example, the DeMPA framework asserts that:
to be predictable and transparent, government
should prepare an annual plan of aggregate
amount of domestic borrowing. The plan—
based on the annual budget cash ow
forecasts—should be made public. The
overall borrowing plan should preferably be
broken down on a monthly basis in an internal
document based on monthly cash ow
forecasts. The government should prepare
the market for the issuance by publishing a
borrowing calendar in advance for wholesale
instruments. (Panzer et al., 2015, p. 38)
This guidance about PFM processes is not
invented from thin air. It draws on the wisdom
and experience of generations of practitioners and
often from the observation of PFM systems in a
wide array of OECD countries. Multiplied across
the many dimensions of 45 separate frameworks,
this represents a substantial canon of conventional
wisdom about the PFM system.
This disciplinary approach of specifying
conventions concerning the desirable
performance of PFM processes has high
practical utility. As discussed earlier, the
approach has provided a conceptual map of
complex territory and is used to serve multiple
purposes. Assessment of conformity with the
conventions, through formal frameworks or
otherwise, provides a starting point for discussing
the PFM system in a particular country (PEFA
Secretariat, 2019). The use of convention-based
assessment frameworks can also satisfy an innate
tendency to want to emulate successful peers
(Lawson, 2012; Di Maggio & Powell, 1983).
These assessments are convenient for assessing
the strength and integrity of government systems
when deciding whether to channel external funds
through government budgets. External nance
providers, including donors and IFIs, can use the
independent assessments as “ready reckoners”
to anchor their judgments. Finally, having a
consistent set of generally applicable metrics over
a long time period permits comparative research
and analysis of trends and correlations.
The benets associated with PFM conventions
also mean, however, that they can become
xed and entrenched, without continuous
evolution based on emerging evidence. There
is a recognized distinction in organization theory
between “single-loop” and “double-loop” learning
within disciplines and organizations (Argyris,
1977) and a wider and closely related discussion
in the literature on learning within organizations
(Argyris & Schön, 1978, 1996; Senge, 1990).
Single-loop learning involves settling on a
conceptual framework and continuing to apply
it, rening the application of the framework but
not the framework itself. In double-loop learning,
feedback from the real world shapes the model
as well as the way in which it is applied. Public
management in general is stuck in a single
loop. The approaches described in the previous
chapter for learning better ways to help countries
conform more closely to the PFM conventions
are important—but ultimately this is still single-
loop learning. Continuously assessing whether the
conventions themselves could be improved would
represent double-loop learning.
The conventions need refreshing
Despite the impressive and valuable
disciplinary strength of PFM as a standalone
agenda in the development sphere, better PFM
is not a result that matters on its own; PFM
is part of the means not of the ends. Chapter
2 discussed the evolving objectives of PFM,
noting that it is important largely because of its
assumed contribution to government actions
and development results. Those include service
42
delivery and sector outcomes, both of which are
of particular interest in this report. The potential
of PFM to make a positive contribution to tangible
results in socioeconomic development has, over
the past decade, prompted a renewed focus by the
international community on trying to understand
the specic ways in which PFM may be relevant
to service delivery.
The knowledge underpinning the PFM
conventions is not certain and has a limited
empirical basis. The performance specications
referenced in PFM assessment frameworks
have not been proven empirically for their
contribution to development results and may not
even be widely observed in OECD countries. For
example, “if there were bullet proof evidence
that having competitive procurement generates
reliable and efcient provision of goods and
services, for instance, we would be safe in
only measuring compliance with competitive
procurement procedures. Unfortunately, we do not
have this evidence, and it must be said that many
OECD countries achieve relatively high levels
of functionality without necessarily complying
with these processes” (Andrews et al., 2014,
pp. 11–12). As noted in Chapter 2, the evidence
indicating that conformity with PFM conventions
is either necessary or sufcient to achieving the
three standard PFM objectives is limited.
Finding the links between PFM and
development results: the example of
service delivery
While it is clear that sound PFM relates to the
government’s effective provision of collective
goods and services, the important empirical
question is how.
1
Those collective goods and
services (often described in shorthand as “public
services,” “public goods,” or “service delivery”)
typically include—but are not limited to—
education, law and order, environmental protection,
national defense, roads and bridges, hospitals and
health care, welfare services, and public transport.
A distinction is made here between provision
through the budget and provision through other
instruments of government, namely subsidies
(although often technically considered a subset of
provision), production, and regulation (Hughes,
2018). Explaining the relationship between
PFM processes and service delivery results in
these areas is difcult. Sound PFM systems are
generally thought to be necessary for delivery, but
there is not a strong or extensive evidence base
for that contribution. The effects of other factors
such as the human resource management system
(for example, inadequate staff competencies and
perverse motivations) makes it clear that PFM
systems alone are also not sufcient for delivery
(Campos & Pradhan, 1996; PEFA Secretariat,
2016; Schick, 1998a; World Bank, 1998). While
it is widely accepted that PFM matters for service
delivery, the specic ways in which it matters are
not well established.
Research into the relationship between PFM
processes and service delivery offers tantalizing
glimpses but few certainties—even in the health
sector, where work is most well-advanced
(Annex H). Focusing on the delivery of efcient,
high-quality, accessible, and equitable public
services is rising fast as a priority for donors and
client governments. It is relatively straightforward
to identify the relevance of PFM conceptually and
anecdotally, but harder to show systematically the
relationships and dependencies. Emergent work
to investigate the links between PFM and service
delivery has looked at the issues in general and in
some specic country cases (Goryakin et al., 2017;
Krause, Sweet, Hedger & Chalise, 2013; Welham
et al., 2017; Welham, Krause & Hedger, 2013;
World Bank, 2016). The most intensive efforts
have focused on the health sector, where there is
burgeoning analytic work starting from both the
PFM and sector perspectives (Goryakin et al., 2017;
Krause et al., 2013; Welham et al., 2017; Welham
et al., 2013; World Bank, 2016; Barroy, Kabaniha,
Boudreaux, Cammack & Bain, 2019; Cashin et al.,
2017; Piatti-Fünfkirchen & Schneider, 2018). The
relationship between PFM and service delivery
has also been the focus of an increasing amount of
work on diagnostic frameworks in the health sector
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
43
(ODI, forthcoming). Yet, despite these initiatives,
knowledge remains partial and tentative.
Health care provides a stark example of the
challenges involved in determining the precise
ways in which PFM matters for service delivery
and, in turn, exactly how service delivery drives
sector outcomes. Welham et al. (2017) nd that
a stronger PFM system is associated with lower
under-ve and infant mortality, and higher life
expectancy at birth. Goryakin et al. (2017) show the
challenges in attributing these outcomes to PFM
systems and refer to Filmer and Pritchett (1999),
who nd that public spending accounts for less
than 1 percent of the variation in child mortality
rates, whereas 95 percent can be explained by
national income per capita, inequality in income
distribution, female education, and religious and
ethno-linguistic diversity. In such a situation, it is
not clear whether the problem is that the services
are not delivered well, that the services are not
delivered at all, or that the services are delivered
but are not relevant to the desired outcomes.
2
In all of these cases, little is known about the
contribution of the PFM system beyond some
general ideas.
The structure of PFM for service delivery
has to deal not only with sectors but also with
subnational governments of various types and
with varying levels of autonomy. Global agendas
such as the SDGs, the Addis Ababa Action
Agenda on nancing for development, the Paris
Agreement on climate change, and the New Urban
Agenda (Habitat III) emphasize the critical role of
subnational governments in service delivery and
nancing for sustainable development. Some of
these agendas specically argue that urban and
metropolitan governments are in a much better
position to manage and coordinate the nancing
of integrated territorial development and to deal
with some elements of climate change than sector
siloes of central government agencies. Multiple
development assistance interventions are already
specically targeting subnational PFM—probably
more than the number focused on PFM in sectors.
Accordingly, decentralization and levels of
government must be considered centrally in any
thinking on how PFM relates to service delivery.
Refreshing the conventions is necessary but
will be challenged
It is not a point of minor pedantry to suggest
a more dynamic approach to revising the
conventions and the frameworks in which
they are embedded. If the conventions stand as
guideposts indicating where discussions might
begin on strengthening PFM processes, then
incorporating or retaining less relevant content
distracts attention and precludes alternative and
better ideas. Revisions to the PEFA framework
in 2016 placed greater emphasis on transparency
and management of liabilities and scal risks, and
on internal control, and widened the scope of the
framework to include extrabudgetary units and
the management of social security funds. While
extensive consultations identied these areas as
priorities, the revisions were not as signicant
as some PFM experts and researchers thought
necessary (Krause et al., 2014). Others have
argued more recently that the PEFA framework
focuses excessively on formal procedures and on
form over function (Hadley & Miller, 2016) and
ignores strategic interactions in the budgeting
process (Andrews, 2007; Dabla-Norris et al.,
2010). Comparing the conventions in the PEFA
framework with assessments conducted by the
United Kingdom’s National Audit Ofce of the
multiyear spending reviews undertaken in the
United Kingdom in 2010 and 2015 (National
Audit Ofce, 2012, 2015, 2018) points to
some dimensions that are not covered by the
PEFA framework (Hood, King & Piotrowska,
forthcoming in 2019).
Adjusting the conventions is not a
straightforward task and will be challenged—
not least because it has implications for
the composition and use of standard PFM
assessment frameworks. For example, PEFA
asks whether a country’s PFM system conforms
to a set of standards that implicitly represent the
conventions. Stability in the conventions and,
44
hence, in the assessment frameworks allows
time series comparisons by providers of nancial
and technical assistance and by researchers
and analysts. To assess country progress, the
frameworks need to be relatively stable over
time and revisions to them need to prioritize
comparability between versions. Furthermore,
technical advisers in PFM and wider groups of
development assistance professionals are now
accustomed to treating the conventions embodied
in PFM assessment frameworks as universally
valid and applicable—across countries and across
government objectives.
3
These conventions have
become highly normative, and there are powerful
organizational and professional incentives that
perpetuate them (Scharfstein & Stein, 1990).
Despite these evident difculties, rethinking the
conventions will be important in ensuring the
continued relevance of PFM as a discipline. Two
approaches may hold promise in this area.
Some ways forward: updating and adapting
the conventions
More actively curating the life cycle of
PFM conventions
Proposal 4: Review the current conventions
embedded in standard PFM assessment
frameworks to test evidence of results and the
degree of applicability in advanced economies
The proposal is to make more explicit the
currently tacit criteria by which PFM
conventions are established and become
embedded in standardized PFM assessment
frameworks. Focusing rst on foundational PFM
processes remains the accepted wisdom of the
PFM discipline, and those “basic” elements have
not ceased to matter (Schick, 1998b). Accordingly,
this report proposes a set of criteria for judging
whether it is appropriate to treat any particular
PFM process and its operational performance as
a “basic,” or foundational, convention that might
then be relevant across countries (Table 3). The
three proposed criteria of rationality, universality,
and empirics echo in part the approach proposed
by Andrews (2008) for how to move “beyond
indicators without theory” in work on good
governance.
Along with establishing which particular
specications of PFM processes may be
suitable for inclusion in standard frameworks,
a corollary is to consider which established
PFM conventions might be “retired” from
the assessment frameworks. That would apply
if the evidence on their applicability turns out to
have been overstated or if there is concern about
excessive promotion in contexts where they are not
well suited. The same criteria would apply in both
instances: considering potential new conventions
and reviewing existing conventions. Among the
many PFM assessment frameworks in existence,
an obvious candidate for such a review would be
the PEFA framework because it covers the whole
PFM system and is among the best-known and
most widely used.
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
45

Case
Criteria ( or X)
Implicaon
1.Raonality
Is it based on clear
reasoningorwell-
accepted theory?
2.Universality
Is it observed
in all advanced
economies?
3.Empirics
Is there
systemac
evidence on
results?
A
Notrequired
Qualiesasafoundaonalelement
ofPFMinallsengs,suitable
foruseinstandardassessment
frameworks
B
X
Qualiesforfurtherconsideraonas
arecommendedarrangementacross
countrysengs
C
X X
Notrecommendedforadopon
withoutcarefulexperimentaonin
eachseng
Note:CaseAaddressesinstancesinwhichparcularspecicaonsofPFMprocessespassboththetestsofraonalityand
universality.CaseBreferstosituaonsinwhichPFMprocessspecicaonspassthersttestofraonalitybutnotthesecond
testofuniversality,andthuswouldneedtobebackedupbysystemicevidenceofresults.CaseCapplieswherethespecicaon
ofaPFMprocessisneitheruniversallyobservednorsupportedbysystemacevidenceofresults.
Source:Authors’formulaon.
The starting point for curating the PFM
conventions is to only consider particular PFM
process specications foundational or generally
valid if they satisfy two criteria. The rst is that
they are rational and based on accepted theory
or other logic. For example, budgets should be
comprehensive so that all claims are considered
together to avoid logrolling. The second is that
they are universal, in the sense that they are found
in all advanced economies. Universality is a proxy
for assuming that the particular PFM process
specications are achievable, practicable, and
strongly associated with successful socioeconomic
development—even if the exact causal link cannot
be ascertained. If particular specications of PFM
processes pass both these tests of rationality
and universality (Case A in Table 3), then it is
reasonable to treat them as PFM conventions
without requiring further evidence. Meeting these
two criteria would therefore be enough to justify
inclusion in standard PFM assessment frameworks
as a working convention.
Where a particular specication of a PFM
process is not universally observed, then
systematic evidence of results across a range
of relevant settings becomes important for
assessing suitability. If proposed PFM process
specications pass the rst test of rationality but
not the second test of universality, then to achieve
the status of recommended conventions they
must be backed up by systematic evidence of
results (Case B). Meeting those two tests would
suggest that the PFM process specication can
be treated as a recommended arrangement across
country settings. The challenge here is that the
external validity of empirical ndings—that is,
their generalizability to other settings—is always
limited.
In cases where the specication of a PFM
process is neither universally observed nor
supported by systematic evidence on results,
then much greater care would be needed with
regard to its application in practice (Case
C). MTEFs and performance-based budgeting
provide examples. To receive an “A” score on
indicator 16.2 on medium-term expenditure
ceilings, the PEFA assessment framework requires
that “aggregate and ministry-level expenditure
46
ceilings for the budget year and the two following
scal years are approved by government before
the rst budget circular is issued” and an “A” score
on indicator 16.4 on consistency of budgets with
the previous years estimates requires that “the
budget documents provide an explanation of all
changes to expenditure estimates between the last
medium-term budget and the current medium-term
budget at the ministry level” (PEFA Secretariat,
2016, p. 48). This specication would not qualify
automatically as a PFM convention because it is
not universally found in advanced economies.
Although there is some positive supporting
evidence (Vlaicu, Verhoeven, Grigoli & Mills,
2014), it is not conclusive across countries (World
Bank, 2012a). Pending clearer empirical evidence,
such PFM process specications would not be
promoted as conventions through standardized
assessment frameworks.
4
Identifying new PFM conventions that matter
for service delivery
Proposal 5: Use PFM assessment frameworks
to collect data and evidence “at the frontier”
to build insights about which aspects of PFM
operational performance matter for service
delivery
Potential future conventions could be found
through data collection “at the frontier”
by scoping out new ideas about how the
performance of PFM processes affects service
delivery, as a prominent example of government
actions. Almost all country-level assessments of
PFM performance are currently both formal and
ofcial. They are formal in the sense that they
rely on the application of one or more assessment
tools and accompanying guidelines about their
methodology and use. They are ofcial in the
sense that international organizations, donors,
or ofcial secretariats are typically responsible
for running, authorizing, validating, or assuring
the assessments and their results. These standard
assessments could be complemented by use of the
same tools—or components of them—for informal
or experimental inquiry with the aim of generating
knowledge rather than measuring performance.
A parallel and complementary step would be
to reappraise how service delivery is addressed
in the standard PFM objectives and to propose
revisions to make the relevant objective more t
for purpose. Table 2 set out an indicative proposal
for a potential reformulation of this objective to
focus more on operational efciency and service
quality: “Government should provide goods and
services at a cost that achieves ongoing efciency
gains and (to the extent appropriate) is competitive
with market prices. It should use modes of
delivery that optimize service quality and ensure
accessibility.” This proposed recasting enhances
the existing coverage of operational efciency
by bringing quality, accessibility, and mode of
delivery explicitly into scope. Once rigorously
developed based on strong theory and evidence,
the proposed new version of the objective
would be disseminated for wide discussion and
consultation.
The dimensions of PFM operational
performance that are most relevant to this
revised objective on service delivery are likely to
be found in the intermediate functions of well-
performing PFM systems. Whereas many of the
current conventions in standard PFM assessment
frameworks are “forms” (or de jure dimensions)
of PFM (Hadley & Miller, 2016; Krause et al.,
2014), there has not been a systematic attempt to
distinguish the conventions that are “functions”
with relevance to service delivery and sector
outcomes. Andrews et al. (2014) posit that a set
of functional specications for PFM processes
could be identied and tested with reference to
desirable intermediate results such as “prudent
scal decisions, credible budgets, reliable and
efcient resource ows and transactions, and
institutionalized accountability” (p. 6). They
break down these result areas into sixteen more
specic “functional concerns” of PFM that seem
to matter for service delivery. Those range from
“cash is provided to spending agencies when
agreed, in agreed amounts” to “concerns raised by
independent assurance exercises are transparently
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
47
discussed by citizens’ representatives, receive
timely follow-up and redress by the executive”
(Andrews et al., 2014, p. 6).
These intermediate result areas represent
attempts to nd further stepping stones in
the results chain, in this case moving from
PFM conventions toward service delivery
and development results. Not all of these result
areas are missing from the standard assessment
frameworks, but current PFM frameworks are
incomplete when it comes to some aspects of
functional performance (Andrews, 2007; Hadley
& Miller, 2016; Hood et al., forthcoming in 2019).
Aspects to integrate might include government
staff perceptions of budget credibility, the
reliability of resource ows and the accuracy of
transactions, sequencing of reforms, and external
assessments of accountability arrangements. Such
metrics would focus on ideas that are of interest
but have not achieved the status of conventions
accepted by the PFM discipline.
Existing PFM assessment approaches can be
accompanied by institutionalized collection of
data that are more speculative and draw on a
wider array of frameworks. This could involve
adapting or honing assessment frameworks or
other analytical tools such as public expenditure
reviews, public expenditure tracking surveys,
and service delivery surveys to learn more about
the relationships between PFM processes and
operational performance on the one hand and
service delivery on the other (Welham et al., 2017).
The tools currently under development by sector
experts and decentralization specialists provide
a rich menu of potential metrics. While some
preliminary work has been done in the health sector
to trace the contributory relationships through
the delivery chain from nancial allocations and
PFM processes downstream to results (World
Bank, 2016), there are few experiments that
compare variations in existing and potential PFM
conventions.
The mechanism for achieving this
institutionalized data collection could be a
virtual and open-access “beta” or “sandbox”
space for experimentation that would be
independent of the funding and afliation
pressure of major assistance providers. It would
be partly an observatory and partly a mechanism
to support inquiry, testing, piloting, and learning
about the effectiveness of PFM (Foster, Rinehart
& Springs, 2019).
5
There is currently no particular
institutional location for data and emergent ideas
on how PFM processes relate to service delivery.
The IMF, World Bank, PEFA Secretariat, and other
assistance providers already act as custodians of
most of the PFM assessment frameworks (Annex
F). Those entities, together with some research
institutions, already conduct long-term tracking
of country progress and trajectories. In expanding
this tracking capability, it would be essential to
involve specialists beyond the PFM discipline.
For example, people working in the sectors and
on subnational or decentralization issues could
collaborate with PFM specialists to develop
metrics and lessons, working backward from the
point of delivery. Government ofcials and service
users would also be important constituencies to
include in the task group.
Harnessing PFM for policy change
We now build on the proposed expansion of the
standard PFM objectives to consider how PFM
processes and technical PFM advice could
better inform and support policy change. The
remainder of this chapter considers how to harness
PFM and its disciplinary conventions to assist
governments in driving strategic reprioritization
in budget policies and scrutinizing the choices and
trade-offs among socioeconomic policy objectives.
Rethinking how PFM relates to public policy
Pressure is mounting for policy change
Policy and political pressures are driving
demand for fundamental changes in how public
nance is managed. A decade ago, Caiden (2010)
observed the looming demands of major policy
challenges:
48
In the face of global developments…
governments will be called on to expand their
investments in infrastructure, edu-cation,
research, energy, and technological innovation,
and to meet urgent challenges, such as nuclear
waste disposal, climate change, terrorism
and natural disasters. Many ‘big questions’
may not have been settled at all. Can existing
budget institutions and processes transcend
their current modes of conducting business to
cope with the demands that will be placed on
them? (p. 209).
Caiden (2010) further anticipated a resurgent
concern for equity and social justice in public
nance, arguing that: “budgets…are what people
and their governments choose to make of them.
They are instruments of economic and social
policy, so budgetary values may need to be
sacriced to more important societal values, social
stability, compassion for those who are unable to
care for themselves, justice, and equity” (p. 209).
Reprioritization of public resources and
redistribution of income and wealth have
recently gained political salience in both
advanced economies and lower-income
countries. Climate change mitigation,
infrastructure development, universal health
care, and reducing marginalization and inequality
have all assumed an even greater force and
resonance in public nance over the past decade,
following the global nancial crisis in the era of
the SDGs, the “leaving no one behind” agenda,
and the Paris Agreement on climate change. At
the forefront of this movement, one country has
shifted to a “well-being budget” (Government
of New Zealand, 2019) and others have made
statutory commitments to mitigate climate change
or have signicant political interests in doing so
(Prime Minister's Ofce, 2019; U.S. House of
Representatives, 2019). The IMF is increasingly
concerned about balancing economic prosperity
with adequate social sector spending and reduced
inequality (Lagarde, 2019).
The PFM discipline has remained detached
from policy questions
An emerging critique of the PFM discipline
in the development sector is that it has added
more inertia into budgetary institutions,
detaching PFM from evolving policy concerns.
“Grand challenges” such as eradicating poverty,
mitigating climate change, and expanding
public infrastructure require reprioritization and
reallocation of public resources on a scale without
much precedent outside of scal crisis episodes.
Rising inequality demands a fundamental
rebalancing of scal policy norms to consider the
distribution of income alongside aggregate scal
objectives. Yet neither of these two objectives
is well-supported by the PFM discipline’s
conventions and approaches.
Managing strategic reprioritization
Budgeting inherently constrains reallocation
Current PFM conventions struggle to support
the pace and scale of policy change and
reallocation needed to tackle grand challenges.
Those conventions are strongly associated
with incrementalism in budgeting (Wildavsky,
1992). Indeed, the budgetary process in essence
“recognizes the priority of old claims, stabilizing
government, giving citizens clear expectations
of continuity in services and entitlements, and
diminishing conict” (Caiden, 2010, p. 208).
Several factors converge to make incremental
adjustment the dominant paradigm over a
more “rationalist” approach in budgeting that
elevates information and analysis as the basis
for budgetary decision making (Fozzard, 2001).
6
These incrementalist traits have increased in
recent years, enhanced by developments such
as medium-term scal frameworks and baseline
budgeting that incorporate multiyear incentives
for policy stability into budgeting arrangements
(Schick, 2013).
7
Just as conformity with PFM conventions
contributes to incrementalism in budgeting, so
problem-based and adaptive approaches lean
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
49
toward incremental change in institutional
reform.
8
In time-honored tradition, decision
makers and their advisers “muddle through”
using a process of “disjointed incrementalism”
(Fozzard, 2001; Lindblom, 1959). The combined
effect is a bias toward continuity and stability in
budgeting and budgets. Even the most concerted
attempts at innovation in tools and processes—
such as the Planning Programming Budgeting
System, zero-based budgeting, Rationalisation des
Choix Budgétaires, and spending reviews—have
not succeeded in overcoming the inherent inertia
in budget policy making (Robinson, 2016).
Learning from past attempts at supporting
policy change
Adjusting the system of conventions to better
equip PFM processes to support major changes
in policy direction will not be an easy task. The
obvious precondition is strong political intention
at the highest level to reallocate resources of any
scale or signicance. Beyond episodes of crisis or
emergency, which can suspend the usual rules of
the game, the question is how PFM conventions
might be recongured to facilitate change instead
of continuity. Even if the desirable direction were
more apparent, the conventions embraced by
the PFM discipline are sticky and only slowly
responsive to new evidence and research ndings.
Attempts to learn lessons from past efforts
at reprioritization and reallocation of public
nance will need to look across country
contexts. There is a rich set of illustrations within
OECD settings of approaches to adapting PFM
processes to address particular policy concerns.
9
The experience of spending reviews has been a
focus of analysis, including studies of episodes
of budgetary reallocation outside of crisis periods
up to 2005 (Kraan & Kelly, 2005). More recently,
in the context of the global nancial crisis and
subsequent austerity programs, the OECD
Working Group of Senior Budget Ofcials has been
reviewing the experience of “strategic spending
reviews”
10
to address the prioritization of public
expenditure and the dimensions of inuence on
allocations (Catalano & Erbacci, 2018; Lau, 2011;
Robinson, 2013).
11
There are some lessons but few
convincing conclusions about what has worked
and what has not. The conclusion for the OECD
is that, although some countries became more
adept at prioritizing the allocation of new scal
space, “little attention was paid to mechanisms to
reprioritize (reallocate) baseline expenditure” and
there is now “widespread desire to build strong
institutions and processes capable reallocating
expenditure, including—but not limited to—
spending reviews” (Robinson, 2016, p. 31).
Some lessons may be learned from previous
attempts in lower-income countries although,
again, there are few successful and positive
examples. Initiatives include pro-poor budgeting
approaches in the 1990s (Carter, 2015),
12
attempts
at gender budgeting that emphasize policy-related
expenditure proposals (Elson, 1999),
13
proposals
on climate change mitigation through a more
fundamental review of budgetary and accounting
procedures as well as options for modeling
climate-related spending (Gilmore & St. Clair,
2018; Ricke, Moreno-Cruz, Schewe, Levermann
& Caldeira, 2016), and the examination of pension
and infrastructure liabilities (IMF, 2018).
Support for pro-poor budgeting initiatives is an
instructive case study. Reforms to PFM processes
introduced in lower-income countries during the
1990s and 2000s, when “pro-poor” expenditure
reforms were heavily promoted, often proved
insufcient to match countervailing incentives and
vested interests.
14
When institutional changes did
lead to increased spending, it was not sufcient
to drive improved results in most cases. Evidence
on the effectiveness of pro-poor budgeting
remains ambiguous (Simson, 2012; Wilhelm
& Fiestas, 2005; Williamson & Canagarajah,
2006),
15
in much the same way that spending
reviews in OECD countries have struggled
to drive successful strategic reprioritization.
16
International agencies eventually lost interest in
pro-poor budgeting approaches, as can be seen
from their disappearance from the discourse
on PFM. It may be the case, though, that these
50
efforts were simply not sustained or supported
sufciently well, instead becoming procedural
triggers for debt relief under the Highly Indebted
Poor Countries initiative.
Managing trade-offs among policy
objectives
Balancing stabilization and distributional
objectives in public finance
Tensions are increasing between policies to
achieve macroeconomic stabilization on the one
hand and more equitable income distribution
on the other. At a time of high and rising inequality
in income and wealth (Milanovic, 2016; van der
Weide & Milanovic, 2014), the negative impact
of scal consolidation linked to stabilization lies
behind many current socio-economic concerns.
17
Changing perceptions about social justice are
creating pressure on governments to implement
stronger and more active redistribution policies
(Mason & Kluegel, 2000; Munro, 2017). Evidence
shows that major episodes of scal consolidation
are associated with a persistent rise in income
inequality (Ostry, Loungani & Berg, 2019). There
is growing support for the argument that the
economic benets of scal consolidation must
be weighed more carefully against the short-run
social costs (Lagarde, 2019).
18
This notion has
prompted greater interest in PFM processes for
examining the likely distributional impact of scal
adjustments, and in institutional arrangements for
incorporating equity considerations and ensuring
that the burden of scal adjustment is spread
fairly and sustainably. The latest IMF review of
program conditionality between 2011 and 2017
found that the quality of scal adjustment under
IMF programs was inadequate and recommended
a greater focus on the quality of social spending
and the impact of program policies on poor and
vulnerable groups (IMF, 2019, p. 26).
Austerity policies implemented in the wake of
the global nancial crisis are an acute, but by no
means exceptional, example of how aggressive
short-term scal contraction can impose severe
welfare costs. Fiscal structural reforms in Greece
starting around 2010 offer an illustration of the
tensions between aggressive scal austerity,
wider social welfare, and political exigencies
(OECD, 2018).
19
It is now widely argued that
the bailout plans were based on overly optimistic
economic scenarios and unrealistic assessments
of what would be politically achievable goals
(Alesina, Favero & Giavazzi, 2019). Indeed, “the
May 2010 agreement committed Greece to an
adjustment that, while not unprecedented in its
size, was unprecedented in the adversity of the
macroeconomic context within which it was to be
implemented” (Ardagna & Caselli, 2014, p. 30).
The general lesson is that more and better analysis
of the effects of austerity policies on income
distribution is required across all cases (Rogoff,
2019).
These concerns and policy dilemmas are now
more routinely debated across country income
groups, from advanced economies to lower-
income countries. That is not to suggest an
equivalence in terms of the levels of hardship or
the obstacles to policy change, but to consider
how better analysis might help in considering
trade-offs. Although the example of the Greek
bailouts is the cause célèbre, scal policies
pursued since 2010 in the United Kingdom are
also under growing international scrutiny. There
is greater questioning of the choice to prioritize
deep and rapid scal retrenchment in pursuit of
macroeconomic stabilization over distributional
concerns (Alston, 2018, pp. 22–23).
20
While
clearly the choice is political, this emphasizes
the importance of using impact analysis more
effectively to inform and support both the
development and the implementation of scal
policy. In the United Kingdom case, it is argued
that “…the government should initiate an expert
assessment of the cumulative impact of tax and
spending decisions since 2010 and prioritize the
reversal of particularly regressive measures”
(Alston, 2018, p. 23).
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
51
Balancing stabilization and allocation
objectives in public finance
Governments across the country income
spectrum are starting to rethink their
approaches to debt and decits. Debates about
the long-term scal sustainability of high levels
of public debt—and the balance between scal
and welfare costs—are now a live feature in
OECD countries and most conspicuously the
United States (Blanchard, 2019; “Economists
Are Rethinking Fiscal Policy,” 2019; Furman
& Summers, 2019). The same applies in lower-
income countries with regard to infrastructure
investment. The prescription of tight scal policy
faces a renewed test as China’s Belt and Road
Initiative reveals some incompatibility between
the scal stringency of conventional PFM and a
debt-nanced and infrastructure-led economic
growth model.
21
Increasing governments’ access
to borrowing from alternative concessional
sources and international capital markets further
compounds those tensions (Haque, Bogoev
& Smith, 2017; Presbitero, Ghura, Adedeji
& Njie, 2015). Continuing debates about the
merits and risks of international nancing from
capital markets or Chinese investment in African
infrastructure are a clear illustration (Chen, 2019).
That realpolitik could shift the nature of analysis
and debate away from efforts to dissuade from
borrowing and toward consideration of trade-offs.
New PFM conventions and new PFM objectives
Global policy and research initiatives to
address inequality are attempting to alter the
policy bias toward aggregate outcomes and to
shift political incentives toward distributional
action and trade-offs. The economics discipline
in international development has already started to
respond.
22
Norms in scal policy share the bias
toward aggregate effects such as scal discipline
and have given a powerful role to scal rules,
scal councils, multiyear frameworks, and accrual
accounting and budgeting. Stronger frameworks
and tools will be needed to assist governments
in evaluating distributional considerations and
examining trade-offs with other policy objectives.
Without taking any political or policy position
on the choices, the case is growing for better
and more multidimensional information and
analysis—allied with stronger participation and
legitimacy—to inform those choices.
This report has proposed expanding and
adapting the three standard objectives of PFM
to support a rebalancing of policy priorities
between scal and socioeconomic outcomes.
Expanding and adapting the PFM objectives
reveals long-standing normative conicts more
strongly and explicitly. “Budget policy involves a
number of distinct objectives, but these overlap in
practice, thereby complicating an efcient policy
design…. It is important to keep in mind that there
are three distinct policy objectives and policy
should try to minimize conicts among them”
(Musgrave & Musgrave, 1989, pp. 13–14). It is a
fundamental task of democratic politics to address
these conicts and attempt to mitigate or resolve
them.
The space for the PFM discipline to contribute
lies in developing processes and conventions for
more active consideration of potential spillover
effects and trade-offs in scal policies.
23
The
potential for conicts applies to both the revenue
and the expenditure side of the budget but, as
noted above, is often most pronounced and most
contentious in the balance between maintaining
a sustainable scal position and ensuring an
equitable distribution of income. Underlying PFM
processes are needed to produce the information
that can help to expose and scrutinize tensions
between prosperity and inclusion in scal policy
choices.

governance
Social justice and the strength of the social
contract have re-emerged as dominant
concerns in public policy. Participation and
accountability matter, both as intrinsic values and
as functional contributions to the achievement
52
of scal objectives and other policy outcomes
(Alt, 2019). Accountability and transparency
emphasize the nuts and bolts of democracy, equity,
and trust (de Renzio, 2019).
24
The connections
to rising concerns about fairness, social justice,
intergenerational equity, and environmental
sustainability are clear to see—although nding
the right response is challenging (Finger &
Gressani, 2014).
25
The PFM discipline can play a stronger role
in opening up PFM processes and conventions
to foster citizen inuence and participation
in scal governance. Closely related to policy
choices and effects are the processes needed to
permit civic participation in ways that can inform
policy decisions and establish their feasibility
and legitimacy. While mainstream advice now
recognizes transparency and participation as
signicant outcomes (IMF, 2017a), these values
seem to be subsidiary rather than foundational.
PFM must retain its classic job description
of supporting scal policy objectives, but not
at the expense of failing to address growing
economic inequality and the erosion of real
incomes, declining trust in government, and rising
intolerance and vulnerabilities to populism and
authoritarianism. The next generation of ideas and
tools for strengthening the voices of citizens in
scal governance must rise to this challenge.
Proponents of a more inclusive perspective have
yet to identify how local- and municipal-level
actions can meaningfully be scaled up to the
national level. It is not clear how to move beyond
small-scale local participatory budgeting processes
(Montambeault, 2015). Few governments have
successfully replicated this type of experience at
the national level or extended public engagement
beyond small infrastructure projects. Mainstream
advice positions transparency and participation
as distinctly modest contributions to this agenda
(IMF, 2017a). Technological advancement may
prove to be a positive driver or enabler of change,
but much of that potential has yet to be achieved
(Peixoto & Sifry, 2017). Some argue that moving
from the small-scale and local to the national level
requires the inclusion of rights-based indicators
that measure whether revenue and expenditure
policies meet people’s needs for food, health
care, housing, education, social protection, and a
healthy environment (Rudiger, 2018). These are
dauntingly high bars to clear (Ubaldi, 2013).
26
Two ideas explored below may help open up PFM
to supporting major policy change and analyzing
policy trade-offs.
Some ways forward: new conventions and
new analytical tools
The comparative advantage of the PFM
discipline lies in its focus on processes and
conventions. PFM processes create a framework
for managing public money and reinforcing scal
policy decisions. The resulting PFM conventions
have tended to emphasize arrangements that lock
in incrementalism and continuity, while scal
policy norms lock in a bias toward prioritizing
scal constraints or other scal objectives. These
issues are predominantly the preserve of scal
policy experts, but the PFM discipline and its
PFM conventions can play an important role.
Exploring how PFM can better support major
policy changes
Proposal 6: Investigate how PFM conventions
and processes could better support non-
incremental policy change through strategic
reprioritization in budget policies
Better understanding how PFM processes
could be used to support changes in policy
direction is a priority. Some investigation
of examples and lessons regarding how PFM
process and conventions have accommodated or
supported instances of major reallocation could
shed light on how innovations in PFM may be
helpful. Given the limited reference points or case
examples of successful strategic reprioritization,
a broader review might need to include episodes
of signicant spending increases (that is, the
allocation of additional public revenue rather than
reallocation within a xed envelope) or cases of
major subsidy reductions. The focus would be on
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
53
PFM dimensions (Kraan & Kelly, 2005), although
the dominant policy dimensions and political
factors would also need to be recognized and
understood.
The starting point would be to take stock of
the lessons learned through many previous
attempts to overcome incrementalism and
increase policy responsiveness in budgeting.
The review would identify the incentives toward
incrementalism, the historical track record of
attempts to move away from incrementalism in
OECD countries, and the lessons emanating from
past and current tools and initiatives. Examples
may include program budgeting, performance-
based budgeting, pro-poor budgeting, spending
reviews or cross-sectoral public expenditure
reviews, MTEFs, and country-specic approaches
such as Public Service Agreements in the United
Kingdom. Examining the success factors in cases
involving the politically difcult task of explicitly
transferring funds from a relatively low-priority
policy area to fund increased spending in an area
of higher priority will be critical.
Another way to approach this question is
to consider the t between particular policy
directions and the PFM processes and
conventions that underpin them. Judgment
will be needed to determine which processes
and conventions are versatile across multiple
policy objectives and which are more bespoke
elements that will support a particular policy
orientation. For example, there may be concurrent
but incompatible needs or pressures to constrain
spending and reduce the decit, to boost the volume
and ow of funds to infrastructure development
and service delivery, and to increase redistributive
transfers to marginalized con-stituencies facing
severe hardship and lack of opportunity. A strong
foundational set of PFM processes can help with
good information and analysis across any of
these priorities. However, different scal policy
orientations may indicate the need for different
processes to try to make those policies effective.
Fiscal rules and independent scal councils are
examples of such institutional innovations.
The purpose behind this proposal is to bring
the PFM discipline and thinking on the
budget process back into the political realm
in a way that functions across, or conforms
to, the specic realities of distinctive political
systems. One approach would be to study a
specic policy area, such as climate change,
to draw lessons on the ways in which current
PFM processes and conventions may impede
or facilitate grand policy adjustments. Drawing
wider lessons from efforts to achieve major sector
reprioritization in budget policy, concrete ideas,
and proposals could be piloted in countries in
real time, building on political demand for these
policy changes. Achieving this would require
assembling a group of policy makers (including
climate policy specialists and nance ministry
ofcials) and politicians that extends beyond the
PFM discipline. This multidisciplinary group
would lead the analysis and recommendations,
then the design, implementation, evaluation, and
dissemination of potential solutions. With the
growing emphasis by IFIs and other development
assistance providers on global public goods, the
venture would take advantage of the expanded
strategic space and demand.
It would be helpful if the work were not limited
to one country income group but conducted
instead as a collaborative initiative across the
income spectrum. Many of the policy challenges
and political pressures are common across
countries—whether as a result of the links to
global public goods or owing to the increasingly
convergent reference points and aspirations
among citizens (Kim, 2017). Many existing tools,
such as spending reviews or their equivalents,
are used across groups of countries. Political
challenges and obstacles apply in all contexts.
Consequently, some innovation in the types of
partnerships that are formed to investigate this
agenda would be valuable, reaching beyond the
usual organizational suspects and bringing in
former political leaders to help with insights about
better connecting technocratic PFM processes
with policy and political considerations.
54
Analyzing trade-offs among policy objectives
Proposal 7: Expand the toolkit of PFM to
analyze the trade-offs among policy objectives
and to consider the socioeconomic impact of
scal and budget policy choices
Demand is growing for the PFM discipline to
play a stronger contributing role in ensuring
that decision makers are better informed about
policy trade-offs and potential socioeconomic
impacts. The dominance of aggregate scal
concerns has arguably biased PFM toward giving
insufcient weight to wider socioeconomic values
and objectives. Yet aims such as reducing poverty,
improving sector outcomes, narrowing income
disparities, and strengthening citizen voice in
governance are increasingly on the radar in
discussions about PFM. There may be objections
from within the PFM discipline, and especially
from scal policy experts, about the risk of
overreach into policy matters. While some debate is
needed about whether this is an appropriate future
direction for the PFM discipline, it is notable that
leading players such as the IMF already appear to
be moving in this direction (Lagarde, 2019).
A useful rst step would be to launch a
reappraisal of the standard objectives in PFM
to make the case for their expansion and to
propose specic new formulations for debate.
Expanding the three long-standing PFM objectives
would make those objectives more relevant to
contemporary priorities and policy concerns.
It would also re-focus attention on the tensions
and trade-offs that exist among some of these
objectives, which had gradually become obscured
over the past two decades. Chapter 2 of this report
sets out an indicative proposal for the potential
reformulation of these objectives (Table 2).
Moving forward, the expanded objectives would be
developed more rigorously based on strong theory
and evidence. Most critically, the potential trade-
offs and tensions could be explained with some
concrete illustrations and current case examples,
especially concerning distributional incidence.
The revised proposed objectives would then be
put out for wide discussion and consultation.
There is a particular need to develop and
test new PFM conventions and supporting
processes that can be used to analyze the
distributional implications of policy choices,
as this is a signicant omission in the current
setup of conventions and frameworks. Several
tools and approaches could be tested, including
greater emphasis given to the revenue side of PFM.
Publication of socioeconomic impact statements
could be required or recommended when a
government proposes a specic scal course—for
example, requiring the assessment of impacts on
public services, income distribution, and poverty
levels. The government or an independent entity
could be required to produce assessments of the
distributional effects of scal and budget policy—
for example, impacts on distinct income quintiles
or on young or old populations in particular.
Governments could be required to publish a pre-
budget statement to encourage public debate and
analysis of policy options, thereby helping to
strengthen the role of the demand side in scal
governance.
Links could be made to the separate proposal to
introduce greater contestation of ideas as part of
the external technical advice provided to client
governments (Proposal 3). The main intention
would be to equip governments themselves with
better analytical tools and operating conventions
as part of their PFM system. These tools could also
be used by external actors to inform dialogue with
governments and technical advice. The core idea
would be to make explicit the trade-offs among
different objectives in managing public nance
as the basis for informed debate and government
decision making (Annex K).
Moving on from here
This chapter has explored some ideas for how to
engage with PFM as a more “open” system that
interacts uidly with public policy—covering
policy choices, government actions, and
development results. The proposals reconsider
Chapter 4: Rethinking Managing Public Finance in an “Open” System
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
55
the objectives of managing public nance and look
at the operational performance of PFM processes
from the perspective of their real-world impact.
They respond to two problems identied in the
introductory chapter of this report: rst, that the
ways in which PFM matters for service delivery
and development results are not well understood
and, second, that the standard objectives and
conventions of PFM are not equipped to deal with
political trade-offs or major policy change. The
nal four International Working Group proposals
are as follows:
(4) Review the current conventions embedded
in standard PFM assessment frameworks
to test evidence of results and the degree of
applicability in advanced economies;
(5) Use PFM assessment frameworks to collect
data and evidence “at the frontier” to build
insights about which aspects of PFM operational
performance matter for service delivery;
(6) Investigate how PFM conventions and
processes could better support non-incremental
policy change through strategic reprioritization
in budget policies; and
(7) Expand the toolkit of PFM to analyze the
trade-offs among policy objectives and to
consider the socioeconomic impact of scal and
budget policy choices.
The next and nal chapter summarizes the
proposals made throughout this report and
considers some of the potential implementation
challenges. It locates the discussion within the
strategic context of how external support for
institutional strengthening may be evolving and
looks at tactics to navigate the organizational
incentives that will affect progress on rethinking
international support for managing public nance.
56
An agenda for change: some
proposals for the PFM discipline
The purpose of this report is to provoke
debate and drive positive change. The report
began with four current problems identied by
the International Working Group on Managing
Public Finance based on extensive consultations
and literature review. Chapter 1 set out the guiding
parameters of the argument developed in this
report about how to rethink international support
for managing public nance in order to make it
more t for purpose in the 2020s.
Chapter 2 summarized the “state of PFM.”
It noted the distinctive strength of the PFM
“discipline” and the path that it has followed,
combining a strong set of conventions about
desirable practices with the growing adoption of
more problem-based and adaptive approaches. It
examined whether the standard PFM objectives
fully reect the range of contemporary policy
concerns and objectives. The chapter concluded
that current working assumptions in PFM represent
a “closed” model for diagnosing shortcomings and
developing proposals for action.
Chapter 3 examined the inuence and utility
of the “closed” model and proposed some ways
to build on its strengths without overstretching
the model. It recommended the development of
better data collection and knowledge-sharing
protocols to drive faster learning about how
technical advice can best support improvements
in PFM. It went on to recommend the introduction
of greater contestation among intervention options
and greater choice by governments as a means to
drive effectiveness.
Chapter 4 proposed some ways to open
up the model that underpins conventional
thinking about the objectives and operational
performance of PFM processes. This thinking
affects the diagnosis of PFM shortcomings and the
development of proposals for action. The chapter
acknowledged that this is difcult territory,
as it begins to depart from the concrete and
“universalist” assumptions of the “closed” model.
It considered the potential for developing a new
generation of approaches to international support
for managing public nance that better reect the
real world. The chapter recommended the more
active curation of PFM conventions based on
emerging evidence, along with experimentation
“at the frontier” to build insights about how
the PFM conventions relate to service delivery
and development results. It also recommended
investigating how PFM can better assist
governments in driving strategic reprioritization
in budget policies and in scrutinizing trade-offs
among socioeconomic policy objectives.
While the Working Group had the benet
of an independent perspective and extensive
consultations, not everyone will agree with
the perspective or the agenda set out in this
report. The aspiration is that the ideas developed
and discussed in the report will form the basis for
some practical action and experimentation—either
through the proposals put forward in response
to the identied problems (Table 4) or through
reactions to them. Improving the international
discourse on PFM and how it relates to advice,
money, and results will require action. This report
attempts to stimulate that action.
5. PUTTING IDEAS INTO PRACTICE
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
57
Table 4: A recap on the problems and proposals
Problem idened in this report Working Group proposals
Proposals that build on the strengths of the exisng
closed” model
Problem1:Thepaceoflearningabouthowexternal
assistancecanbeersupportimprovementsinPFMis
tooslow
(1)Assessoersoftechnicaladviceagainststandards
fortheprovisionofinformaonandevidencejusfying
theapproachandfortheplanneddisseminaonof
dataaboutimpact
(2)Establishpraconergroupstosharesensive
performanceinformaononPFMintervenonsona
voluntaryandcondenalbasistoidenfywaysof
improvingperformance
Problem2:Developmentagencies’preference
forfollowingacommonapproachhasreduced
opportuniestotestideasthroughcompeon
(3)Experimentwith“managedchoice”intheprovision
oftechnicaladvice,withacoalionoffundersand
clientgovernmentsandthecreaonofadedicated
fundingfacility
Proposals that envisage PFM as an “open” system
Problem3:ThewaysinwhichPFMmaersfor
servicedeliveryanddevelopmentresultsarenotwell
understood
(4)Reviewthecurrentconvenonsembeddedin
standardPFMassessmentframeworkstotestevidence
ofresultsandthedegreeofapplicabilityinadvanced
economies
(5)UsePFMassessmentframeworkstocollectdata
andevidence“atthefroner”tobuildinsightsabout
whichaspectsofPFMoperaonalperformancemaer
for service delivery
Problem4:Thestandardobjecvesandconvenonsof
PFMarenotequippedtodealwithpolicaltrade-os
ormajorpolicychange
(6)InvesgatehowPFMconvenonsandprocesses
couldbeersupportnon-incrementalpolicychange
throughstrategicrepriorizaoninbudgetpolicies
(7)ExpandthetoolkitofPFMtoanalyzethetrade-
osamongpolicyobjecvesandtoconsiderthe
socioeconomicimpactofscalandbudgetarypolicy
choices
Building a persuasive case for change: some initial ideas
Navigating development agency
incentives is critical
Another report, another set of recommenda-
tions. Why would any ofcial funder or
development agency want to take action to pursue
the ideas or implement the proposals in this
report? While the Working Group takes the view
that these recommendations will contribute to the
effectiveness of the PFM discipline in the medium
term, we acknowledge that they pose non-trivial
nancial and opportunity costs in the short term.
There are challenging time inconsistencies and
free-rider problems at play. Looked at from the
point of view of individual development agencies,
there is a question about why any one agency
would choose to invest in signicant new piloting,
research, and learning that would benet the eld
as a whole. Collective action among agencies may
be even more difcult to muster.
The Working Group recognizes the entrenched
and long-standing challenges of navigating
and inuencing development agency incentives
(Coyle et al, 2005; de Renzio et al, 2005). A good
place to start might be in thinking about how to
maintain a development focus on strengthening
public sector institutions. This agenda is a
major claimed comparative advantage of the
multilateral development system that provides
most international support for PFM. If agencies
58
recognize the strategic necessity to evolve—
for both external impact and institutional self-
interest—it may then be possible to mobilize
effort in support of ideas such as those set out in
this report.
The “institutions matter” argument may
be losing its force
There is a risk in not taking action. Professionals
in the PFM discipline, and in development agencies
more generally, are now used to an environment
in which institutional reform is accepted as the
point of entry to sustained improvements in public
sector performance. However, institutional reform
has been a relatively recent focus of development
assistance—dating largely from the mid-1990s
(Annex J). There is no reason to assume that it
will remain central to development assistance
efforts if it cannot make a direct and convincing
claim to supporting the evolving set of high-
priority development objectives. As this report
has highlighted, causal linkages between PFM
systems and results are currently more suggestive
than established. Combining the approaches of
conformity with conventions and of politically
aware diagnosis is promising, but it owes more
to recent development assistance traditions than
empirically based condence.
Development fashion could change again, with
a shift toward emphasizing policy outcomes
while leaving institutions to follow however
they can. Development assistance is diminishing
in political signicance as it declines in relative
nancial weight. Non-aid instruments are coming
to the forefront, including trade, remittances,
other nancial ows, and more general cultural
links. Similarly, classic development concerns
are waning as the number of lower-income
countries declines and more countries start to
transition from aid.
1
This change may well have
political consequences for the commitment to
support institutional reform and, more broadly,
the “governance agenda” of the past two decades.
PFM is a prominent aspect in that agenda and
is currently emphasized in external support for
lower-income and aid-dependent countries.
Predictions suggest that the focus on country-
level institutional strengthening may be
displaced in the future by a wider, more
dynamic set of priorities for development
cooperation. These arguments have been building
in force since the start of the decade as part of the
growing agenda on cross-border issues and global
public goods. One prominent thought leader in
global development has articulated this direction
of travel as follows:
Instead of today’s ODA there will be two
other major sources of ofcial outside funding
for developing countries. First will be lending
by multilateral…and national… development
nance institutions from their hard windows at
below market prices… Second will be transfers
from high-income countries to developing
countries in support of global public goods,
e.g. to protect forests, to subsidize clean energy
and compensate for fossil fuels not exploited,
to underwrite pandemic surveillance, and for
spending to undercut cross-border non-state
terrorism, piracy, drug and sex trafcking, etc.
Transfers in support of global public goods
will not necessarily go more to poorer than to
middle-income countries, as tends to be the
case today; they will go where they can be
most effectively deployed at the lowest cost.
(Birdsall, 2013)
The incentives could diminish for development
agencies to focus on complex institutional
reforms that cannot readily be shown to have
development impact or satisfy donor countries’
national interest. The risk is that agencies will
shift their strategic focus, instead redoubling
their efforts to tackle the symptoms of poverty,
where there will be quicker, more tangible, and
more certain results—in other words, politically
visible results (Barder, 2018). PFM may therefore
lose support on two fronts as development
cooperation focuses on global public goods such
as climate change mitigation and post-pandemic
reconstruction and infection control, and on direct
Chapter 5: Putting Ideas into Practice
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
59
development results in areas such as humanitarian
aid, health, nutrition, and sustainable water sources.
A call for proactive leadership
As a professional group, the PFM discipline
has made signicant and well-recognized
progress in analyzing and arguing the case
for PFM strengthening to be a central issue in
development. There has evidently been impressive
leadership and consensus building on an agenda,
its pertinence, and its conventions. Each of the 45
different PFM assessment tools (PEFA Secretariat,
2018) is associated with a distinct group of experts
who understand and own that framework. There
are also some well-published “new realist” thought
leaders who have been critical and inuential in
the task of developing more problem-based and
adaptive approaches (CID, 2014; Andrews, 2013;
Andrews et al., 2012; Blum et al., 2012; Booth,
2014; Booth & Unsworth, 2014; World Bank,
2000, 2012b). Bringing together the insights
and tools of these complementary groups of
thinkers and practitioners might produce powerful
leadership in rethinking how institution building
can support a changing development agenda. They
could act as a powerful guild for the development
and implementation of recommendations. The
coronavirus pandemic has started to catalyze some
thinking about the task for PFM (Gupta and Barry
2020; Gurazada et al., 2020; Saxena and Stone,
2020).
Development agencies will need to demonstrate
institutional-level leadership and some
willingness to direct nancial resources to
these ideas or new approaches. This is uncertain
territory, and some of the proposals are deliberately
speculative. Active experimentation and learning
will be required from the outset. Leaders in the
PFM discipline might take up these ideas, and
progress might be kick-started by funding for one
or more of the proposals set out in this report. It is
hoped that a small coalition—perhaps comprising
bilateral, multilateral, and foundation actors—
could come together to explore the agenda and
drive tangible progress. The Working Group itself
has no leverage or vested interest in any particular
way of proceeding. These ideas are submitted for
further debate, development, and testing in the
interest of contributing to improvements in PFM
and, ultimately, development results.
Moving on from here
This report contains a lot of words but not the
nal one. The Working Group has been privileged
with the time and opportunity to reect on a vital
area of international development activity. It has
benetted from extensive and generous advice,
as well as lessons and insights from experience
and from a large number of practitioners, policy
makers, and researchers. Although the Working
Group stands by the proposals and hopes they will
be picked up and taken up, they are ultimately
just examples of how to push PFM forward.
The mission now is to continue to learn more
from empirical observations, celebrate rather
than obscure political debate, and ensure the
continued contribution of a group of development
practitioners who have already contributed to
signicant results, with the aim of ensuring the
future relevance and effectiveness of the PFM
discipline within the overall development agenda.
60
CHAPTER REFERENCES
References for Chapter 1
Andrews, M. (2013). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Annen, K., & Moers, L. (2012). Donor Competition for Aid Impact, and Aid Fragmentation. Washington DC: IMF.
Barder, O. (2009). Beyond Planning: Markets and Networks for Better Aid. Washington DC: Center for Global
Development.
Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation. (2018). Goalkeepers Data Report. Seattle, Washington: Institute for Health
Metrics and Evaluation, University of Washington.
Booth, D. (2011). Aid effectiveness: bringing country ownership (and politics) back in. Working Paper 336. London:
Overseas Development Institute (ODI).
Bourguignon, F., & Platteau, J.-P. (2015). The Hard Challenge of Aid Coordination. World Development, 69, 86–97.
Coady, D., & Murgasova, Z. (2019). A Strategy for IMF Engagement on Social Spending. Washington DC: IMF.
Coats, D. R. (2019). Statement for the Record: Worldwide Threat Assessment of the US Intelligence Community.
Washington DC: Senate Select Committee on Intelligence.
Custer, S., DiLorenzo, M., Masaki, T., Sethi, T., & Harutyunyan, A. (2018). Listening to Leaders 2018: Is
Development Cooperation Tuned-in or Tone-Deaf? Williamsburg, VA: AidData, College of William &
Mary.
de Renzio, P. (2009). Taking Stock: What Do PEFA Assessments Tell Us About PFM Systems across Countries?
London: ODI.
Department of Foreign Affairs and Trade (DFAT), Australia. (2019). Framework for Engaging on Public Financial
Management. Canberra: DFAT.
Dijkstra, L., Poelman, H., & Rodríguez-Pose, A. (2018). The Geography of EU Discontent. Brussels: European
Union.
Easterly, W. (2002). The Cartel of Good Intentions: The Problem of Bureaucracy in Foreign Aid. The Journal of
Policy Reform, 5(4), 223–50.
Easterly, W. (2009). The Cartel of Good Intentions. Foreign Policy. Retrieved from https://foreignpolicy.
com/2009/11/11/the-cartel-of-good-intentions/
Elson, D. (1999). Gender Budget Initiative: Background Papers. London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
Fritz, V., Verhoeven, M., & Avenia, A. (2017). Political Economy of Public Financial Management Reforms:
Experiences and Implications for Dialogue and Operational Engagement (121436). Washington DC:
World Bank Group. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/28887
Gaspar, V., Amaglobeli, D., Garcia-Escribano, M., Prady, D., & Soto, M. (2019). Fiscal Policy and Development:
Human, Social, and Physical Investment for the SDGs. Washington DC: IMF.
Gilmore, E. A., & St. Clair, T. (2018). Budgeting for Climate Change: Obstacles and Opportunities at the US State
Level. Climate Policy, 18(6), 729–41.
Greenhill, R., Prizzon, A., & Rogerson, A. (2013). The Age of Choice: Developing Countries in the New Aid
Landscape. London: ODI.
Hudson Institute. (2016). The Index of Global Philanthropy and Remittances (2016). Washington DC: Hudson
Institute.
International Labour Organization (ILO). (2018). Global Wage Report 2018/19. Geneva: ILO.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). (2018a). 2018 Review of the Fund’s Capacity Development Strategy—Overview
Paper. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2018b). World Economic Outlook (October 2018): Challenges to Steady Growth. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2019). 2018 Review of Program Design and Conditionality (Policy Paper No. 19/012). Washington DC:
IMF.
IEG. (2018). Approach Paper: Public Finance for Development Evaluation. Washington DC: World Bank.
Inter-Agency Group on Economic and Financial Statistics. (2019). The Financial Crisis and Information Gaps: G20
Data Gaps Initiative (DGI-2). Washington DC: Financial Stability Board and IMF.
Joint World Bank/IMF/PEFA Public Expenditure Working Group. (2006). Supporting Better Country Public
Financial Management Systems: Towards a Strengthened Approach to Supporting PFM Reform –
Consultative Paper. In OECD. (2006). Harmonising Donor Practices for Effective Aid Delivery (Volume 2:
Budget Support, Sector Wide Approaches and Capacity Development in Public Financial Management).
Paris: OECD.
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
61
Keating, M. (2001). Public Management Reform and Economic and Social Development. OECD Journal on
Budgeting, 1(2).
Kharas, H., McArthur, J. W., & Rasmussen, K. (2018). How Many People Will the World Leave Behind?
Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Klein, M., & Harford, T. (2005). The Market for Aid. Washington DC: International Finance Corporation.
Koch, S., Leiderer, S., Faust, J., & Molenaers, N. (2017). The Rise and Demise of European Budget Support:
Political Economy of Collective European Union Donor Action. Development Policy Review, 35(4),
455–73.
Lagarde, C. (2019). Forging a Stronger Social Contract—the IMF’s Approach to Social Spending [Press release].
Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2019/06/14/sp061419-md-social-spending
Manning, N., & Wetzel, D. (2010). Tales of the Unexpected: Re-Building Trust in Government. In O. Canuto & M.
Giugale (Eds.), The Day after Tomorrow: A Handbook on the Future of Economic Policy in the Developing
World (pp. 163–81). Washington DC: World Bank.
Milanovic, B. (2016). The Winners and Losers of Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
OECD. (2006). Harmonising Donor Practices for Effective Aid Delivery (Volume 2: Budget Support, Sector Wide
Approaches and Capacity Development in Public Financial Management). Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2018). Economic Survey of Greece. Paris: OECD.
PEFA Secretariat. (2018). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
Pritchett, L., Samji, S. & Hammer, J. (2013). It's All About MeE: Using Structured Experiential Learning ("E") to
Crawl the Design Space. Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Rios-Avila, F. (2015). Decade of Declining Wages: From Bad to Worse. Baltimore: Levy Economics Institute.
Samman, E., Lucci, P., Hagen-Zanker, J., Bhatkal, T., Simunovic, A. T., Nicolai, S., Stuart, E., & Caron, C. (2018).
SDG Progress: Fragility, Crisis and Leaving No One Behind. London: ODI.
Schick, A. (2013). Reections on Two Decades of Public Financial Management Reforms. In M. Cangiano, T. R.
Curristine, & M. Lazare (Eds.), Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture (pp. 21–78).
Washington DC: IMF.
Schick, A. (2019). An Introduction to Budgeting: Everywhere Budgeting Is the Same and Different. Budgeting and
Public Expenditures in OECD Countries 2019 (pp. 19–30). Paris: OECD.
Schmaljohann, M., & Prizzon, A. (2015). Age of Choice: How Developing Countries Are Managing the New Aid
Landscape. London: ODI.
Shanmugaratnam, T., Ahmed, S., Babacan, A., Belka, M., Frenkel, J. A., Issing, O., Ito, T., Lustig, N., Okonjo-
Iweala, N., Rajan, R. G., Saccomanni, F., Stern, N., Taylor, J. B., Trichet, J.-C., Velasco, A., & Min, Z.
(2018). Making the Global Financial System Work for All: Report of the G20 Eminent Persons Group on
Global Financial Governance. Washington DC: G20.
United Nations. (2019). Report of the Secretary-General on SDG Progress 2019. New York: United Nations.
van der Weide, R., & Milanovic, B. (2014). Inequality Is Bad for Growth of the Poor (but Not for That of the Rich).
Washington DC: World Bank.
Weingast, B. R., Shepsle, K. A., & Johnsen, C. (1981). The Political Economy of Benets and Costs: A Neoclassical
Approach to Distributive Politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89(4), 642–64.
Welham, B., Hart, T., Mustapha, S., & Hadley, S. (2017). Public Financial Management and Health Service
Delivery: Necessary, but Not Sufcient? London: ODI.
Wildavsky, A. (1992). The New Politics of the Budget Process. New York: Harper Collins.
World Bank. (2019a). Global Economic Prospects: Darkening Skies. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2019b). Global Economic Prospects: Heightened Tensions, Subdued Investment. Washington DC:
World Bank.
References for Chapter 2
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty. New
York: Crown Publishers.
Alesina, A., Hausmann, R., Hommes, R., & Stein, E. (1999). Budget Institutions and Fiscal Performance in Latin
America. Working Paper Series 394. Washington DC: IADB. Retrieved from http://www.iadb.org/OCE/
pdf/394.pdf
Allen, R. (2018). Book Review: Building State Capability: Evidence, Analysis, Action. Governance(31), 401–03.
Allen, R., & Grigoli, F. (2012). Enhancing the Capability of Central Finance Agencies (Economic Premise No. 73).
Washington DC: World Bank.
62
Allen, R., Grigoli, F., & Howard, N. (2011). Enhancing the Capabilities of Central Finance Agencies: Synthesis
Report. Washington DC: World Bank.
Allen, R., Hemming, R., & Potter, B. (Eds.). (2013). The International Handbook of Public Financial Management.
London: Palgrave MacMillan.
Allen, R., & Krause, P. (2013). The Role, Responsibilities, Structure and Evolution of Central Finance Agencies.
In R. Allen, R. Hemming, & B. H. Potter (Eds.), The International Handbook of Public Financial
Management (pp. 98-115). Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave MacMillan.
AlphaBeta. (2018). The Landscape of PFM Reform in Developing Countries: Trends in Financing and
Implementation of PFM Reforms over 2002–16. Singapore: AlphaBeta.
Andrews, M. (2007). What Would an Ideal Public Finance Management System Look Like? In A. Shah (Ed.),
Budgeting and Budgetary Institutions (pp. 359–86). Washington DC: World Bank.
Andrews, M. (2008a). The Good Governance Agenda: Beyond Indicators without Theory Oxford Development
Studies, 36(4), 379–407.
Andrews, M. (2008b). Good Government Means Different Things in Different Countries. Cambridge, MA: Kennedy
School of Government. Retrieved from http://web.hks.harvard.edu/publications/getFile.aspx?Id=324
Andrews, M. (2013). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Andrews, M. (2014). Why Distributed End Users Often Limit Public Financial Management Reform Success.
Cambridge, MA: Center for International Development at Harvard University.
Andrews, M., Cangiano, M., Cole, N., de Renzio, P., Krause, P., & Seligmann, R. (2014). This Is PFM. Cambridge,
MA: Center for International Development at Harvard University.
Andrews, M., McNaught, T., & Samji, S. (2018). Opening Adaptation Windows onto Public Financial Management
Reform Gaps in Mozambique. CID Faculty Working Paper No. 341. Cambridge, MA: Center for
International Development at Harvard University.
Andrews, M., Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2012). Escaping Capability Traps through Problem-Driven Iterative
Adaptation (PDIA) (Working Paper 299). Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Annett, A. (2002). Politics, Government Size, and Fiscal Adjustment in Industrial Countries. Washington DC: IMF.
Bain, K. A., Booth, D., & Wild, L. (2016). Doing Development Differently at the World Bank: Updating the
Plumbing to Fit the Architecture. London: ODI.
Bakir, C., & Jarvis, D. S. L. (2018). Institutional and Policy Change: Meta-Theory and Method. In C. Bakir & D.
S. L. Jarvis (Eds.), Institutional Entrepreneurship and Policy Change (pp. 1–38). New York: Palgrave
MacMillan.
Batley, R., & McLoughlin, C. (2015). The Politics of Public Services: A Service Characteristics Approach. World
Development, 74, 275–85.
Becher, T., & Trowler, P. R. (2001). Academic Tribes and Territories, Buckingham. Buckingham, UK: The Society
for Research into Higher Education and Open University Press.
Blum, J. R., Manning, N., & Srivastava, V. (2012). Public Sector Management Reform: Toward a Problem-
Solving Approach. Washington DC: World Bank. Retrieved from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/
EXTPREMNET/Resources/EP100.pdf
Booth, D. (2011). Working with the Grain and Swimming against the Tide: Barriers to Uptake of Research Findings
on Governance and Public Services in Low-Income Africa. London: ODI.
Booth, D. (2014). Aiding Institutional Reform in Developing Countries: Lessons from the Philippines on What
Works, What Doesn't, and Why. London: ODI.
Booth, D. (2015). Five Myths About Governance and Development. Retrieved from http://blogs.worldbank.org/
publicsphere/blog-post-month-ve-myths-about-governance-and-development
Booth, D., & Unsworth, S. (2014). Politically Smart, Locally Led Development. London: ODI.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Crosby, B. L. (2002). Managing Policy Reform. Bloomeld CT: Kumarian.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Ingle, M. D. (1989). Integrating Blueprint and Process: A Structured Flexibility Approach to
Development Management. Public Administration and Development, 9, 487–503.
Brooke, P. (2003). Study of Measures Used to Address Weaknesses in Public Financial Management Systems in the
Context of Policy Based Support. Final Report. Washington DC: PEFA Secretariat.
Campbell, C. (2001). Juggling Inputs, Outputs, and Outcomes in the Search for Policy Competence: Recent
Experience in Australia. Governance, 14(2), 253–82.
Campos, E., & Pradhan, S. (1996). Budgetary Institutions and Expenditure Outcomes (Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1646). Washington DC: World Bank.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
63
Cangiano, M., Curristine, T., & Lazare, M. (2013a). Introduction. In M. Cangiano, T. R. Curristine, & M. Lazare
(Eds.), Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture (pp. 1–20). Washington DC: IMF.
Cangiano, M., Curristine, T. R., & Lazare, M. (Eds.). (2013b). Public Financial Management and Its Emerging
Architecture. Washington DC: IMF.
Cangiano, M., Gelb, A., & Goodwin-Groen, R. (2019). Public Financial Management and the Digitalization of
Payments. Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Case, K. E. (2008). Musgrave’s Vision of the Public Sector: The Complex Relationship between Individual, Society
and State in Public Good Theory. Journal of Economics and Finance, 32, 348–355.
Center for International Development (CID) at Harvard University, Building State Capability Program. (2014). The
DDD Manifesto. ‘Doing Development Differently’ workshop. Retrieved from http://buildingstatecapability.
com/the-ddd-manifesto/
Clarke, A., & Craft, J. (2019). The Twin Faces of Public Sector Design. Governance, 32(1), 5–21.
de Renzio, P. (2006). Aid, Budgets and Accountability: A Survey Article. Development Policy Review, 24(6),
627–45.
de Renzio, P. (2009). Approach & Methodology for the Evaluation of Donor Support to Public Finance Management
(PFM) Reform in Developing Countries (Part A - Assessing Budget Institutions and Budget Reforms in
Developing Countries: Overview of Theoretical Approaches and Empirical Evidence). Oxford, UK: Fiscus
Public Finance Consultants, Ltd.
de Renzio, P. (2013). Assessing and Comparing the Quality of Public Financial Management Systems: Theory,
History and Evidence. In R. Allen, R. Hemming, & B. H. Potter (Eds.), The International Handbook of
Public Financial Management (pp. 137–60). Basingstoke, UK: Palgrave MacMillan.
Derviş, K., Chandy, L., Kharas, H., Medler, A., & Unger, N. (2011). Global Development under Pressure.
Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Diamond, J. (2013). Good Practice Note on Sequencing PFM Reforms. Washington DC: PEFA Secretariat.
Dom, R., & Miller, M. (2018). Reforming Tax Systems in the Developing World: What Can We Learn from the Past?
London: ODI.
Dressel, B., & Brumby, J. (2009). Enhancing the Capabilities of Central Finance Agencies: From Diagnosis to
Action. Washington DC: World Bank.
Drucker, P. (1974). Management. London: Butterworth Heinemann.
Dunn, W. N. (1988). Methods of the Second Type: Coping with the Wilderness of Conventional Policy Analysis.
Policy Studies Review, 7(4), 720–37.
Ear, S. (2009). Cambodia’s Patient Zero: The Political Economy of Foreign Aid and Avian Inuenza (Working Paper
No. 398). Stanford, CA: Stanford Center for International Development.
Ellerman, D. (2005). Helping People Help Themselves: From the World Bank to an Alternative Philosophy of
Development Assistance. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Evans, P. (2004). Development as Institutional Change: The Pitfalls of Monocropping and the Potentials of
Deliberation. Studies in Comparative Institutional Development, 38(4), 30–52.
Evans, P., & Rauch, J. E. (1999). Bureaucracy and Growth: A Cross-National Analysis of the Effects of ‘Weberian’
State Structures on Economic Growth. American Sociological Review 64(5), 748–765.
Fritz, V., Fialho Lopes, A. P., Hedger, E., Tavakoli, H., & Krause, P. (2011). Public Financial Management Reforms
in Post-Conict Countries: Synthesis Report. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Levy, B., & Ort, R. (Eds.). (2014). Problem-Driven Political Economy Analysis. Washington DC: World
Bank.
Fritz, V., Lopes, A. P. F., Hedger, E., Tavakoli, H., & Krause, P. (2012). Public Financial Management Reforms in
Post-Conict Countries: Synthesis Report. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Sweet, S., & Verhoeven, M. (2014). Strengthening Public Financial Management: Exploring Drivers and
Effects. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Verhoeven, M., & Avenia, A. (2017). Political Economy of Public Financial Management Reforms:
Experiences and Implications for Dialogue and Operational Engagement (121436). Washington DC:
World Bank Group. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/28887
Gore, A. (1995). From Red Tape to Results: Creating a Government That Works Better and Costs Less. Washington
DC: White House.
Grindle, M. S. (2013). Public Sector Reform as Problem-Solving? Comment on the World Bank's Public Sector
Management Approach for 2011 to 2020. International Review of Administrative Science, 79(3), 398–405.
64
Guy, M. E. (2003). Ties That Bind: The Link between Public Administration and Political Science. The Journal of
Politics, 65(3), 641–55.
Hallerberg, M., & Yläoutinen, S. (2010). Political Power, Fiscal Institutions and Budgetary Outcomes in Central and
Eastern Europe. Journal of Public Policy, 30(1), 45–62.
Hausmann, R., Pritchett, L., & Rodrik, D. (2005). Growth Accelerations. Journal of Economic Growth, 10(4),
303–29.
Heifetz, R. A. (1994). Leadership without Easy Answers. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Hood, C. (1991). A Public Management for All Seasons? Public Administration, 69(Spring), 3–19.
Howlett, M. (2009). Governance Modes, Policy Regimes and Operational Plans: A Multi-Level Nested Model of
Policy Instrument Choice and Policy Design. Policy Sciences, 42(1), 73–89.
Hughes, O. (2018). Public Management and Administration: An Introduction (5th Edition). London: Palgrave.
IMF. (2010). Strategies for Fiscal Consolidation in the Post-Crisis World. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2018a). 2018 Review of the Fund’s Capacity Development Strategy—Report of the External Advisory Group.
Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2018b). Fiscal Transparency Handbook. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2018c). Macroeconomic Developments and Prospects in Low-Income Developing Countries. Washington
DC: IMF.
Jakobsen, M., & Jensen, R. (2014). Common Method Bias in Public Management Studies. International Public
Management Journal, 18(1), 3–30.
Keating, M., & Holmes, M. (1990). Australia's Budgetary and Financial Management Reforms. Governance, 3(2),
168–85.
Keefer, P. (2013). Organizing for Prosperity Collective Action, Political Parties and the Political Economy of
Development (Policy Research Working Paper 6583). Washington DC: World Bank.
Kettl, D. F. (2000). Public Administration at the Millennium: The State of the Field. Journal of Public
Administration Research and Theory, 10(1), 7–34.
Key, V. O. (1940). The Lack of a Budgetary Theory. American Political Science Review, 34(6), 1137–44.
Khemani, S. (2013). Buying Votes Vs. Supplying Public Services Political Incentives to Under-Invest in Pro-Poor
Policies (Policy Research Working Paper 6339). Washington DC: World Bank.
Kirkpatrick , D. L., & Kirkpatrick, J. D. (2009). Implementing the Four Levels: A Practical Guide for Effective
Evaluation of Training Programs. Oakland, California: Berrett-Koehler Publishers.
Krause, P., Hadley, S., Mustapha, S., & Welham, B. (2016). The Capabilities of Finance Ministries. London: ODI.
Krishnan, A. (2009). What Are Academic Disciplines? Southampton UK: ESRC National Centre for Research
Methods, University of Southampton.
Kristensen, J. K. (2019, February 28, 2019). [Email].
Lassen, D. D. (2010). Fiscal Consolidations in Advanced Industrialized Democracies: Economics, Politics, and
Governance. Copenhagen: University of Copenhagen.
Levy, B. (2014). Working with the Grain: Integrating Governance and Growth in Development Strategies. Oxford:
Oxford University Press.
Lindblom, C. (1959). The Science of Muddling Through. Public Administration Review, 19, 79–88.
Love, P., & Stockdale-Otárola, J. (Eds.). (2017). Debate the Issues: Complexity and Policy Making. Paris: OECD.
Manning, N. (2001). The Legacy of the New Public Management in Developing Countries. International Review of
Administrative Sciences, 67(2), 297–312.
Melchor, O. H. (2008). Managing Change in OECD Governments: An Introductory Framework. Paris: OECD.
Morgan, P. (2006). The Concept of Capacity. Maastricht, Netherlands: European Centre for Development Policy
Management.
Musgrave, R. A., & Musgrave, P. B. (1989). Public Finance in Theory and Practice (Fifth Edition). San Francisco:
McGraw Hill.
Mustapha, S., & Long, C. (2019). PEFA, Public Financial Management, and Good Governance. Washington DC:
World Bank.
Naidu, S., Rodrik, D., & Zucman, G. (2019). Economics for Inclusive Prosperity: An Introduction (Research Brief).
Economists for Inclusive Prosperity.
Nikitina, S. (2005). Cognition and Instruction. Pathways of Interdisciplinary Cognition, 23(3), 389–425.
North, D. C., Wallis, J. J., Webb, S. B., & Weingast, B. R. (2007). Limited Access Orders in the Developing World:
A New Approach to the Problems of Development, Policy Research Working Paper 4359. Washington DC:
World Bank. Retrieved from http://www-wds.worldbank.org/external/default/WDSContentServer/IW3P/IB
/2007/09/19/000158349_20070919115851/Rendered/PDF/WPS4359.pdf
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
65
OECD. (1995). Governance in Transition: Public Management Reforms in OECD Countries. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2005). Modernising Government: The Way Forward. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2010). Fiscal Consolidation: Requirements, Timing, Instruments and Institutional Arrangements. Paris:
OECD.
Orr, D. W. (1993). The Problem of Disciplines/the Discipline of Problems. Conservation Biology, 7(1), 10–12.
Paudyn, B. (2014). Credit Ratings and Sovereign Debt: The Political Economy of Creditworthiness through Risk and
Uncertainty. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
PEFA Secretariat. (2016). PEFA: Framework for Assessing Public Financial Management. Washington DC: PEFA
Secretariat. Retrieved from https://pefa.org/sites/default/les/PEFA%20Framework_English.pdf
PEFA Secretariat. (2018a). PEFA Handbook Volume III: Preparing the PEFA Report. Washington DC: PEFA.
PEFA Secretariat. (2018b). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
PEFA Secretariat. (2019). PEFA Handbook Volume IV: Using PEFA to Support Public Financial Management
Improvement. Washington DC: PEFA.
Plant, J. F., Stalebrink, O. J., & Vasavada, T. (2010). Public Values, Public Ofcial Associations, and
Professionalism: A Cross-National Analysis. The American Review of Public Administration, 40(6),
722–41.
Pollitt, C. (2008). Time, Policy, Management: Governing with the Past. New York: Oxford University Press.
Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2011). Public Management Reform: A Comparative Analysis (Third ed.). Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2018). Public Management Reform: A Comparative Analysis—Into the Age of Austerity.
Oxford: OUP.
Premchand, A. (1993). Public Expenditure Management. Washington DC: IMF.
Premchand, A. (2000). Control of Public Money: The Fiscal Machinery in Developing Countries. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
Pressman, J. L., & Wildavsky, A. B. (1973). Implementation: How Great Expectations in Washington Are Dashed in
Oakland. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Pritchett, L., Samji, S. & Hammer, J. (2013). It's All About MeE: Using Structured Experiential Learning ("E") to
Crawl the Design Space. Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2004). Solutions When the Solution Is the Problem: Arraying the Disarray in
Development. World Development, 32(2), 191–212.
Raadschelders , J. C. N. (2018). Comparative Public Administration in a Globalizing World: A New Psychological
Challenge Next to the Traditional Scholarly Challenges Paper presented at the American Society for Public
Administration, March 9-13, 2018, Denver.
Ringold, D. (2012). Citizens and Service Delivery: Assessing the Use of Social Accountability Approaches in Human
Development. Washington DC: World Bank.
Roberts, A. (2018). The Aims of Public Administration: Reviving the Classical View Perspectives on Public
Management and Governance, 1(1), 73–85.
Rodrik, D. (2008). One Economics, Many Recipes: Globalization, Institutions, and Economic Growth. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Rossi, F. M., Caperchione, E., Cohen, S., & Brusca, I. (2019). Financial Management and Public Sector Accounting
in an Age of Reforms: Developments and Changes in Public Sector Financial Management. In E. Ongaro
(Ed.), Public Administration in Europe: The Contribution of EGPA (pp. 235–47). London: Palgrave
macMillan.
Sayre, W. S. (1958). Premises of Public Administration: Past and Emerging. Public Administration Review, 18(2),
102–05.
Schick, A. (1996). The Spirit of Reform: Managing the New Zealand State Sector in a Time of Change. Wellington,
New Zealand: State Services Commission and The Treasury.
Schick, A. (1998a). A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (35116). Washington DC:
World Bank Institute.
Schick, A. (1998b). Why Most Developing Countries Shouldn't Try New Zealand's Reforms. The World Bank
Research Observer, 13(1), 123–31.
Scott, G., Bushnell, P., & Sallee, N. (1990). Reform of the Core Public Sector: New Zealand Experience.
Governance, 3(2), 138–67.
Sheely, R. (2014). Mobilization, Participatory Planning Institutions, and Elite Capture: Evidence from a Field
Experiment in Rural Kenya. World Development, 67, 251–66.
66
So, S., Woolcock, M., April, L., Hughes, C., & Smithers, N. (Eds.). (2018). Alternative Paths to Public Financial
Management and Public Sector Reform: Experiences from East Asia. Washington DC: World Bank.
Squire, S. J., & Beazley, I. (2016). Increasing Professionalism in Public Finance Management: A Case Study of the
United Kingdom. Washington DC: World Bank.
Stein, H. (2008). Beyond the World Bank Agenda. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
TADAT Secretariat. (2015). TADAT Assessment Tool: Field Guide. Washington DC: IMF.
Thomas, M. A. (2010). What Do the Worldwide Governance Indicators Measure? The European Journal of
Development Research, 22(1), 31–54.
Unegbu, A. O. (2014). Theories of Accounting: Evolution & Developments, Income-Determination and Diversities
in Use. Research Journal of Finance and Accounting, 5(19), 1–15.
Vitale, J. E. (2013). An Essay on the Division between Craft-Based and Knowledge-Based Professions as an
Inhibitor of Interprofessional Healthcare Education and Practice, Part I. Health and Interprofessional
Practice, 1(3), 1–4.
von Hagen, J. (1998). Budgeting Institutions for Aggregate Fiscal Discipline (ZEI Working Paper, No. B 01). Bonn:
Rheinische Friedrich-Wilhelms-Universität Bonn, Zentrum für Europäische Integrationsforschung.
von Hagen, J. (2006). Political Economy of Fiscal Institutions. In B. Weingast & D. Whitman (Eds.), The Oxford
Handbook of Political Economy (pp. 464–78). Oxford: Oxford University Press.
von Hagen, J., & Harden, I. (1995). Budget Processes and Commitment to Fiscal Discipline. European Economic
Review, 39(3-4), 771–79.
Weber, M. (1978). Economy and Society (Vol. 2). Berkely, CA: University of California Press.
Wildavsky, A. (1992). The New Politics of the Budget Process. New York: Harper Collins.
Williamson, J. (1989). What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In J. Williamson (Ed.), Latin American
Readjustment: How Much Has Happened. Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.
Williamson, J. (2004). The Washington Consensus as Policy Prescription for Development (Lecture Delivered at the
World Bank on January 13, 2004). Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (1997). World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World. New York: Oxford
University Press for the World Bank.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2000). Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank Strategy.
Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2012a). Beyond the Annual Budget: Global Experience with Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks.
Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2012b). The World Bank’s Approach to Public Sector Management 2011–2020: Better Results from
Public Sector Institutions. Washington DC: World Bank.
Wyplosz, C. (2011). Fiscal Discipline: Rules Rather Than Institutions. National Institute Economic Review, 217(1),
R19–R30.
Yanguas, P., & Hulme, D. (2014). Can Aid Bureaucracies Think Politically? The Administrative Challenges of
Political Economy Analysis in DFID and the World Bank. Manchester, UK: Effective States and Inclusive
Development Research Centre.
Zafarullah, H., & Huque, A. S. (2012). Managing Development in a Globalized World. London: Taylor and Francis.
References for Chapter 3
AlphaBeta. (2018). The Landscape of PFM Reform in Developing Countries: Trends in Financing and
Implementation of PFM Reforms over 2002–16. Singapore: AlphaBeta.
Anderson, R. (2005). Transport Performance and the Data Clubs Approach. Paper presented at the Where Does
Britain Rank? – International Public Services Rankings (13th December 2005), London.
Andrews, M. (2012). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Andrews, M., & Manning, N. (2015). The EIP Peer-to-Peer Learning Guide. Paris: Effective Institutions Platform,
OECD.
Annen, K., & Moers, L. (2012). Donor Competition for Aid Impact, and Aid Fragmentation. Washington DC: IMF.
Barder, O. (2009). Beyond Planning: Markets and Networks for Better Aid. Washington DC: Center for Global
Development.
Barder, O., Gavas, M., Maxwell, S., & Johnson, D. (2010). Governance of the Aid System and the Role of the EU.
Paper presented at the Conference On Development Cooperation in Times Of Crisis and on Achieving the
MDGs, Madrid.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
67
Bates, M. A., & Glennerster, R. (2017). The Generalizability Puzzle. Stanford Social Innovation Review, Summer
2017.
Berg, E. (1993). Rethinking Technical Cooperation: Reforms for Capacity Building in Africa. New York: UNDP
Regional Bureau for Africa and Development Alternatives Inc.
Bhattacharya, A., Kharas, H., Plant, M., & Prizzon, A. (2018). The New Global Agenda and the Future of the
Multilateral Development Bank System Washington DC and London: Brookings, CGD, and ODI.
Birdsall, N., & Savedoff, W. D. (2010). Cash on Delivery: A New Approach to Foreign Aid. Washington DC: Center
for Global Development.
Booth, D. (2013). Facilitating Development an Arm’s Length Approach to Aid. London: ODI.
Bourguignon, F., & Platteau, J.-P. (2015). The Hard Challenge of Aid Coordination. World Development, 69, 86–97.
Brooke, P. (2003). Study of Measures Used to Address Weaknesses in Public Financial Management Systems in the
Context of Policy Based Support. Washington DC: PEFA.
Brookings Institution & Center for Global Development (CGD). (2011). Avoidance of Project Implementation Units.
Retrieved from Quality of Ofcial Development Assistance (QuODA) Database at https://www.cgdev.org/
sites/all/cms_iframes/quoda_2014/bar.php?g=2&agency_group=none
Browne, S. (2012). Aid and Inuence, Do Donors Help or Hinder? Abingdon, Oxford: Earthscan Routledge.
CABRI. (2014). Towards a Greater Use of Country Systems in Africa: Recent Trends and New Approaches. Pretoria,
South Africa: Collaborative African Budget Reform Initiative.
Calvard, T. S. (2016). Big Data, Organizational Learning, and Sensemaking: Theorizing Interpretive Challenges
under Conditions of Dynamic Complexity. Management Learning, 47(1), 65–82.
Courty, P., & Marschke, G. (2004). An Empirical Investigation of Gaming Responses to Explicit Performance
Incentives. Journal of Labor Economics, 22(1), 23–56.
De Lay, S., Mills, L., Jadeja, K., & Lucas, B. (2015). Public Financial Management Evidence Mapping.
Birmingham, UK: GSDRC, University of Birmingham.
de Renzio, P., Andrews, M., & Mills, Z. (2010). Evaluation of Donor Support to Public Financial Management
(PFM) Reform in Developing Countries: Analytical Study of Quantitative Cross-Country Evidence.
Stockholm: SIDA.
de Renzio, P., & Rogerson, A. (2005). Power to Consumers? A Bottom-up Approach to Aid Reform. London: ODI.
Dendura, J., & Flynn, N. (2011). Towards a Common Approach to Risk (Paper Prepared for the EC). Brussels:
European Commission.
DFID. (2009). Guidance on Using the Revised Logical Framework London: DFID. Retrieved from http://www.dd.
gov.uk/Documents/publications1/how-to-guid-rev-log-fmwk.pdf
Diamond, J. (2012). Guidance Note on Sequencing PFM Reforms. Washington DC: EC, IMF and PEFA.
Diamond, J. (2013). Good Practice Note on Sequencing PFM Reforms. Washington DC: PEFA Secretariat.
Ellerman, D. (2005). Helping People Help Themselves: From the World Bank to an Alternative Philosophy of
Development Assistance. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
Eno, J., Glentworth, G., Hedger, E., & White, M. (2018). Public Finance, Accountability and Anti-Corruption in
Sierra Leone: Scoping Study for a New DFID Programme. London: DFID.
Evans, A. (2008). Civil Service Reform Thematic Paper Prepared for the Public Sector Reform Evaluation Project.
Washington DC: World Bank.
Fengler, W., & Kharas, H. (2010). Delivering Aid Differently: Lessons from the Field. Washington DC: Brookings
Institution Press.
Fritz, V., Hedger, E., & Lopes, A. P. F. (2011). Strengthening Public Financial Management in Postconict
Countries. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Sweet, S., & Verhoeven, M. (2014). Strengthening Public Financial Management: Exploring Drivers and
Effects. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Verhoeven, M., & Avenia, A. (2017). Political Economy of Public Financial Management Reforms:
Experiences and Implications for Dialogue and Operational Engagement (121436). Washington DC:
World Bank Group. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/28887
Glaister, S., & Anderson, R. (2005). Transport Performance and the Data Clubs Approach. Paper presented at the
ESRC International Public Service Rankings (December 2005), London.
Goodhart, C. A. E. (1975). Problems of Monetary Management: The UK Experience. Papers in Monetary
Economics, Reserve Bank of Australia.
Green, D. (2018). Can ‘Doing Development Differently’ Only Succeed If Aid Donors Stay Away from It? Retrieved
from http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/can-doing-development-differently-only-succeed-if-aid-donors-stay-away-
from-it/
68
Greenhill, R., Prizzon, A., & Rogerson, A. (2013). The Age of Choice: Developing Countries in the New Aid
Landscape. London: ODI.
Gulrajani, N. (2017). Bilateral Donors and the Age of the National Interest: What Prospects for Challenge by
Development Agencies? World Development, 96, 375–89.
HM Treasury (United Kingdom). (2018). The Green Book: Central Government Guidance on Appraisal and
Evaluation. London: HM Treasury.
Hadley, S., & Miller, M. (2016). PEFA: What Is It Good For? London: ODI.
Hanauer, L., & Morris, L. J. (2014). Chinese Engagement in Africa: Drivers, Reactions and Implications for U.S.
Policy. Santa Monica, CA: RAND National Defense Research Institute.
Haque, T. A., Knight, D. S., & Jayasuriya , D. S. (2012). Capacity Constraints and Public Financial Management in
Small Pacic Island Countries. Washington DC: World Bank.
Harris, D. (2011). Emerging Donors: Differentiation, Ownership and Harmonisation. The Networker(98), 8–11.
Honig, D. (2018). Navigation by Judgment: Why and When Top Down Management of Foreign Aid Doesn’t Work.
New York: Oxford University Press.
Hood, C. (2006). Gaming in Targetworld: The Targets Approach to Managing British Public Services. Public
Administration Review, 66(4), 515–21.
Hood, C., Dixon, R., & Wilson, D. (2009). ‘Managing by Numbers’: The Way to Make Public Services Better?
Retrieved from http://www.publicservices.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/policy-brieng-nov2009.pdf
IEG. (2018). Approach Paper: Public Finance for Development Evaluation. Washington DC: World Bank.
Ingram, G., & Lord, K. M. (2019). Global Development Disrupted: Findings from a Survey of 93 Leaders.
Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
Inter-Agency Group on Economic and Financial Statistics. (2019). The Financial Crisis and Information Gaps: G20
Data Gaps Initiative (DGI-2). Washington DC: Financial Stability Board and IMF.
Khemani, S. (2017). Demand and Supply Curves in Political Markets: Understanding the Problem of Public Goods
and Why Governments Fail Them (Policy Research Working Paper 8213). Washington DC: World Bank.
Klein, M., & Harford, T. (2005). The Market for Aid. Washington DC: International Finance Corporation.
Koch, S., Leiderer, S., Faust, J., & Molenaers, N. (2017). The Rise and Demise of European Budget Support:
Political Economy of Collective European Union Donor Action. Development Policy Review, 35(4),
455–73.
Krause, P., Hadley, S., Hedger, E., de Renzio, P., Gill, S., & Andrews, M. (2014). Joint Response to the PEFA
Consultation: We Need a Stronger Summary Assessment. London: ODI.
Lauria, V., & Fumagalli, C. (2019). Brics, the Southern Model, and the Evolving Landscape of Development
Assistance: Toward a New Taxonomy. Public Administration and Development, 1–16.
Lawson, A. (2012). Evaluation of Public Financial Management Reform in Burkina Faso, Ghana and Malawi
2001–2010: Final Synthesis Report. Oxford, UK: Fiscus Public Finance Consultants, Ltd.
Lazer, D., Kennedy, R., King, G., & Vespignani, A. (2014). The Parable of Google Flu: Traps in Big Data Analysis.
Science, 343(6176), 1203–05.
Le Grand, J. (2007). The Other Invisible Hand: Delivering Public Services through Choice and Competition.
Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Le Grand, J. (2010). Knights and Knaves Return: Public Service Motivation and the Delivery of Public Services.
International Public Management Journal, 13(1), 56–71.
Lubienski, C. (2009). Do Quasi-Markets Foster Innovation in Education?: A Comparative Perspective. Paris:
OECD.
Lum, T. (2009). China’s Assistance and Government – Sponsored Investment Activities in Africa, Latin America, and
Southeast Asia. Washington DC: Congressional Research Service.
Martens, B. (2005). Why Do Aid Agencies Exist? Development Policy Review, 23(6), 643–63.
McKechnie, A., & Davies, F. (2013). Localising Aid: Is It Worth the Risk? London: ODI.
Mills, L. (2018). Donor Support to Strengthen Public Financial Management in Partner Countries: Outcomes,
Experiences, and Ways Forward. Brighton, UK: Institute of Development Studies.
Morrison, J. S. (2013). Introduction. In J. S. Morrison (Ed.), Global Health Policy in the Second Obama Term.
Washington DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies.
Mosley, P. (1985). The Political Economy of Foreign Aid: A Model of the Market for a Public Good. Economic
Development and Cultural Change, 33(2), 373–93.
O’Keefe, J. (2007). Aid: From Consensus to Competition? Paper presented at the Brookings Blum Roundtable
(August 3, 2007), Washington DC.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
69
ODI/OECD. (2014). The New Development Finance Landscape: Developing Countries’ Perspective (Working Draft
Presented at the OECD Workshop on Development Finance on 25 June 2014). Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2017). Strengthening the Results Chain: Synthesis of Case Studies of Results-Based Management by
Providers. Paris: OECD DAC.
OECD DAC. (2003). Measuring Performance in Public Financial Management. Harmonising Donor Practices for
Effective Aid Delivery. Paris: OECD.
Olivié, I., & Pérez, A. (2016). Why Don’t Donor Countries Coordinate Their Aid? A Case Study of European Donors
in Morocco. Progress in Development Studies, 16(1), 52–64.
Orth, M., Schmitt, J., Krisch, F., & Oltsch, S. (2017). What We Know About the Effectiveness of Budget Support:
Evaluation Synthesis. Bonn, Germany: German Institute for Development Evaluation.
PEFA Secretariat. (2016). PEFA: Framework for Assessing Public Financial Management. Washington DC: PEFA
Secretariat. Retrieved from https://pefa.org/sites/default/les/PEFA%20Framework_English.pdf
PEMPAL Steering Committee. (2012). PEMPAL Strategy 2012–17. Washington DC: World Bank.
Peterson, S. (2010). Reforming Public Financial Management in Africa Cambridge Mass.: Harvard Kennedy
School.
Porter, D., Allen, B., & Thompson, G. (1991). Development in Practice – Paved with Good Intentions. London and
New York: Routledge.
Power, M., Scheytt, T., Soin, K., & Sahlin, K. (2009). Reputational Risk as a Logic of Organizing in Late Modernity.
Organization Studies, 30, 301–24.
Pretorius, C., & Pretorius, N. (2009). Review of Public Financial Management Reform Literature. London: DFID.
Pritchett, L., & Sandefur, J. (2013). Context Matters for Size: Why External Validity Claims and Development
Practice Do Not Mix. Journal of Globalization and Development, 4(2), 161–97.
Pritchett, L., Woolcock, M., & Andrews, M. (2010). Capability Traps? The Mechanisms of Persistent
Implementation Failure (Background Paper for the 2011 World Development Report on Development,
Conict and Fragile States). Washington DC: World Bank.
Prizzon, A. (2014). The Age of Choice: Papua New Guinea in the New Aid Landscape. London: ODI.
Radelet, S. (2015). The Great Surge: The Ascent of the Developing World. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Reinsberg, B. (2018). Blockchain Technology and the Governance of Foreign Aid. Journal of Institutional
Economics, 2018, 1–17.
Santiso, J., & Frot, E. (2010). Crushed Aid: Why Is Fragmentation a Problem for International Aid? VOX
CEPR Policy Portal. Retrieved from https://voxeu.org/article/crushed-aid-why-fragmentation-problem-
international-aid
Scharfstein, D., & Stein, J. (1990). Herd Behavior and Investment. American Economic Review, 80(June), 465–79.
Schick, A. (1998a). A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (35116). Washington DC:
World Bank Institute.
Schick, A. (1998b). Why Most Developing Countries Should Not Try New Zealand’s Reforms. World Bank
Research Observer (International), 13, 23–31.
Schick, A. (2019). An Introduction to Budgeting: Everywhere Budgeting Is the Same and Different. In Budgeting
and Public Expenditures in OECD Countries 2019 (pp. 19–30). Paris: OECD.
Schmaljohann, M., & Prizzon, A. (2014). The Age of Choice: Fiji and Vanuatu in the New Aid Landscape. London:
ODI.
Scott, Z. (2011). Evaluation of Public Sector Governance Reforms 2001–2011: Literature Review Oxford, UK:
Oxford Policy Management.
Simson, R., Sharma, N., & Aziz, I. (2011). A Guide to Public Financial Management Literature: For Practitioners
in Developing Countries. London: ODI.
Stevens, M. (2004). Institutional and Incentive Issues in Public Financial Management Reform in Poor Countries.
Washington DC: World Bank.
Szulanski, G. (1996). Exploring Internal Stickiness: Impediments to the Transfer of Best Practice within the Firm.
Strategic Management Journal, 17(Special Issue: Knowledge and the Firm), 27–43.
Team Technologies. (2005). The Log Frame Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
Teskey, G., & Tyrrel, L. (2017). Thinking and Working Politically in Large, Multi-Sector Facilities: Lessons to Date.
Canberra ACT, Australia: Abt Associates.
United States Agency for International Development (USAID). (2014). Guide to Public Financial Management.
Washington DC: USAID Ofce of Economic Policy, Capacity Building Division.
Valters, C. (2015). Theories of Change: Time for a Radical Approach to Learning in Development. London: ODI.
70
Valters, C., & Whitty, B. (2017). The Politics of the Results Agenda in DFID: 1997–2017. London: ODI.
Van Dooren, W. (2006). Performance Measurement in the Flemish Public Sector: A Supply and Demand Approach.
Leuven, Belgium: Faculty of Social Sciences.
Van Dooren, W., Manning, N., Malinska, J., Kraan, D.-J., Sterck, M., & Bouckaert, G. (2006). Issues in Output
Measurement for "Government at a Glance": OECD Gov Technical Paper 2. Paris: OECD.
Vogel, I. (2012). Review of the Use of ‘Theory of Change’ in International Development. London: DFID.
Welham, B., Hart, T., Mustapha, S., & Hadley, S. (2017). Public Financial Management and Health Service
Delivery: Necessary, but Not Sufcient? London: ODI.
Wildy, H. (2004). The Data Club: Helping Schools Use Accountability Data. Yearbook of the National Society for
the Study of Education, 103(2), 155–68.
Wilson, D. (2010). Targets, Choice and Voice: Accountability in Public Services. London: 2020 Public Services
Trust.
Woods, N. (2008). Whose Aid? Whose Inuence? China, Emerging Donors and the Silent Revolution in
Development Assistance. International Affairs, 84(6), 1205–21.
Woolcock, M. (2013). Using Case Studies to Explore the External Validity of ‘Complex’ Development Interventions.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Kennedy School.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2002). Thailand's Hurdle Approach to Budget Reform. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank (2010). Safeguards and Sustainability Policies in a Changing World. IEG, World Bank, Washington
DC.
World Bank. (2013). Program Results Framework: Public Expenditure Management Network in Asia (PEMNA),
P129651. Washington DC: World Bank.
References for Chapter 4
Ababou, A. (2019). Building PFM Capabilities Programme: Year 2 in Retrospect. Retrieved from https://www.cabri-
sbo.org/en/blog/2019/building-pfm-capabilities-programme-year-2-in-retrospect
Abiad, A., Furceri, D., & Topalova, P. (2015). The Macroeconomic Effects of Public Investment: Evidence from
Advanced Economies. Washington DC: IMF.
Agénor, P.-R., & Moreno-Dodson, B. (2006). Public Infrastructure and Growth: New Channels and Policy
Implications. Washington DC: World Bank.
Alesina, A., Favero, C., & Giavazzi, F. (2019). Austerity : When It Works and When It Doesn't. Princeton NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Allen, R. (2019, March 11, 2019). [Email].
Alston, P. (2018). Statement on Visit to the United Kingdom by Professor Philip Alston (United Nations Special
Rapporteur on Extreme Poverty and Human Rights). Retrieved from https://www.ohchr.org/en/
NewsEvents/Pages/DisplayNews.aspx?NewsID=23881&LangID=E
Alt, J. E. (2019). Twenty Years of Transparency Research (Keynote Speech at “Public Sector Economics 2018 –
Fiscal Openness: Transparency, Participation and Accountability in Fiscal Policies” in Zagreb on October
26, 2018). Cambridge, MA: Institute of Public Finance, International Budget Partnership and Friedrich-
Ebert-Stiftung.
Andrews, M. (2007). What Would an Ideal Public Finance Management System Look Like? In A. Shah (Ed.),
Budgeting and Budgetary Institutions (pp. 359–86). Washington DC: World Bank.
Andrews, M. (2008). The Good Governance Agenda: Beyond Indicators without Theory. Oxford Development
Studies, 36(4), 379–407.
Andrews, M., Cangiano, M., Cole, N., de Renzio, P., Krause, P., & Seligmann, R. (2014). This Is PFM. Cambridge,
MA: Center for International Development at Harvard University.
Ardagna, S., & Caselli, F. (2014). The Political Economy of the Greek Debt Crisis: A Tale of Two Bailouts.
American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 6(4), 291–323.
Argyris, C. (1977). Double Loop Learning in Organizations. Harvard Business Review(September 1977).
Argyris, C., & Schön, D. (1978). Organizational Learning: A Theory of Action Perspective. Reading, MA: Addison
Wesley.
Argyris, C., & Schön, D. (1996). Organizational Learning II: Theory, Method and Practice. Reading, MA: Addison
Wesley.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
71
Atkinson, T., Grice, J., Simkins, A., Freitas, L. D., Hemingway, J., King, B., Lee, P., Lyon, M., Mai, N., Mehmi, S.,
Pritchard, A., Snelling, J., Tuke, A., Watson, L., & Fletcher-Cooke, G. (2005). Measurement of Government
Output and Productivity for the National Accounts. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Barroy, H., Kabaniha, G., Boudreaux, C., Cammack, T., & Bain, N. (2019). Leveraging Public Financial
Management for Better Health in Africa: Key Bottlenecks and Opportunities for Reform. Geneva: World
Health Organization.
Blanchard, O. (2019). Public Debt: Fiscal and Welfare Costs in a Time of Low Interest Rates (Policy Brief 19-2).
Washington DC: Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Caiden, N. (2010). Challenges Confronting Contemporary Public Budgeting: Retrospectives/Prospectives from
Allen Schick. Public Administration Review, 70(2), 203–10.
Campos, E., & Pradhan, S. (1996). Budgetary Institutions and Expenditure Outcomes (Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1646). Washington DC: World Bank.
Cangiano, M. (2017). Of Rating and Ranking in the Comparison of Fiscal Institutions. Journal of Comparative
Policy Analysis: Research and Practice, 19(4), 377–89.
Carter, B. (2015). Pro Pro-Poor National Budgets. Birmingham, UK: GSDRC, University of Birmingham.
Cashin, C., Bloom, D., Sparkes, S., Barroy, H., Kutzin, J., & O'Dougherty, S. (2017). Aligning Public Financial
Management and Health Financing: Sustaining Progress toward Universal Health Coverage. Geneva:
WHO.
Catalano, G., & Erbacci, A. (2018). A Theoretical Framework for Spending Review Policies at a Time of
Widespread Recession. OECD Journal on Budgeting, 2017(2).
Chen, Y. (2019). Ethiopia and Kenya Are Struggling to Manage Debt for Their Chinese-Built Railways. Quartz
Africa. Retrieved from https://qz.com/africa/1634659/ethiopia-kenya-struggle-with-chinese-debt-over-sgr-
railways/
Clements, B. J., de Mooij, R. A., Gupta, S., & Keen, M. (Eds.). (2015). Inequality and Fiscal Policy. Washington
DC: IMF.
Collier, P., & Hoefer, A. (2005). Resource Rents, Governance, and Conict. Journal of Conict Resolution, 49(4),
625–33.
Dabla-Norris, E., Allen, R., Zanna, L.-F., Prakash, T., Kvintradze, E., Lledo, V., Yackovlev, I., & Gollwitzer, S.
(2010). Budget Institutions and Fiscal Performance in Low-Income Countries. Washington DC: IMF.
de Renzio, P. (2019). Putting the ‘Public’ Back into Public Finance: How Better Budgets Can Save Democracy.
Di Maggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. (1983). The Iron Cage Revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective
Rationality in Organizational Fields. American Sociological Review, 48(April), 147–60.
Economists Are Rethinking Fiscal Policy. (2019). The Economist (May 16, 2019).
Elson, D. (1999). Gender Budget Initiative: Background Papers. London: Commonwealth Secretariat.
European Commission. (2013). A Vision for Public Services (Draft Version). Brussels: European Commission, DG
Connect. Retrieved from http://ec.europa.eu/digital-agenda/en/news/vision-public-services
European Commission. (2019). Financial Assistance to Greece: Information on the Enhanced Surveillance
Framework for Greece. Retrieved from https://ec.europa.eu/info/business-economy-euro/economic-and-
scal-policy-coordination/eu-nancial-assistance/which-eu-countries-have-received-assistance/nancial-
assistance-greece_en
Filmer, D., & Pritchett, L. (1999). The Impact of Public Spending on Health: Does Money Matter? Social Science
and Medicine, 49(10), 1309–23.
Finger, H., & Gressani, D. (2014). Toward New Horizons: Arab Economic Transformation Amid Political
Transitions. Washington DC: IMF.
Foster, A. K., Rinehart, A. K., & Springs, G. R. (2019). Piloting the Purchase of Research Data Sets as Collections:
Navigating the Unknowns. Libraries and the Academy, 19(1), 315–28.
Fozzard, A. (2001). The Basic Budgeting Problem: Approaches to Resource Allocation in the Public Sector and
Their Implications for Pro-Poor Budgeting (Working Paper 147). London: ODI.
Furman, J., & Summers, L. (2019). Who’s Afraid of Budget Decits? How Washington Should End Its Debt
Obsession. Foreign Affairs, March/April 2019.
Gilmore, E. A., & St. Clair, T. (2018). Budgeting for Climate Change: Obstacles and Opportunities at the US State
Level. Climate Policy, 18(6), 729–41.
Goryakin, Y., Revill, P., Mirelman, A., Sweeney, R., Ochalek, J., & Suhrcke, M. (2017). Public Financial
Management and Health Service Delivery: A Literature Review. London: ODI.
Government of New Zealand. (2019). The Wellbeing Budget. Wellington, New Zealand: Department of the Prime
Minister and Cabinet.
72
Hadley, S., & Miller, M. (2016). PEFA: What Is It Good For? London: ODI.
Haque, T., Bogoev, J., & Smith, G. (2017). Push and Pull: Emerging Risks in Frontier Economy Access to
International Capital Markets. Washington DC: Macroeconomics and Fiscal Management (MFM) Global
Practice, World Bank.
Hood, C., King, M., & Piotrowska, B. (2019 (forthcoming)). Evaluating the Efcacy of Expenditure Control over
Time: A New Standard Approach? Oxford: Blavatnik School of Government, Oxford, Nufeld and the
ESRC History of UK Public Expenditure Control Project.
Howell, T. J. (2013). IMF Chief: U.S. Dance with the Debt Limit Is ‘Very, Very Concerning.’, October 13, 2013.
Retrieved from https://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2013/oct/13/imf-chief-us-dance-debt-limit-very-
very-concerning/.
Hughes, O. (2018). Public Management and Administration: An Introduction (5th Edition). London: Palgrave.
Hughes, R. (2019, March 11, 2019). [Email].
IMF. (2010). Imf Survey Online: Interview with Olivier Blanchard. Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/en/News/
Articles/2015/09/28/04/53/sonew090910a
IMF. (2017a). Fiscal Monitor: Tackling Inequality. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2017b). Gender Budgeting in G7 Countries. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2018). Fiscal Monitor: Managing Public Wealth. Washington DC: IMF.
IMF. (2019). 2018 Review of Program Design and Conditionality (Policy Paper No. 19/012). Washington DC: IMF.
Kim, J. (2017). Growing Aspirations of People around the World—How Do We Meet Them? Retrieved from https://
olc.worldbank.org/about-olc/growing-aspirations-people-around-world-how-do-we-meet-them
Kraan, D.-J., & Kelly, J. (2005). Reallocation: The Role of Budgetary Institutions. Paris: OECD.
Krause, P., Hadley, S., Hedger, E., de Renzio, P., Gill, S., & Andrews, M. (2014). Joint Response to the PEFA
Consultation: We Need a Stronger Summary Assessment. London: ODI.
Krause, P., Sweet, S., Hedger, E., & Chalise, B. (2013). Operational Risk Assessment of Public Financial
Management Reform in Nepal: A Review of Challenges and Opportunities. Washington DC: World Bank.
Lagarde, C. (2019). Forging a Stronger Social Contract—The IMF’s Approach to Social Spending [Press release].
Retrieved from https://www.imf.org/en/News/Articles/2019/06/14/sp061419-md-social-spending
Lau, E. (2011). Typology and Implementation of Spending Reviews – Discussion Paper (OECD Senior Budget
Ofcials Network on Performance and Results – 7th Annual Meeting, 9-10 November 2011). Paper
presented at the Working Party of Senior Budget Ofcials, Paris.
Lawson, A. (2012). Evaluation of Public Financial Management Reform in Burkina Faso, Ghana and Malawi
2001–2010: Final Synthesis Report. Oxford, UK: Fiscus Public Finance Consultants, Ltd.
Lin, J. Y., & Wang, Y. (2017). Development Beyond Aid: Utilizing Comparative Advantage in the Belt and Road
Initiative to Achieve Win-Win. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development, 1(2), 149–67.
Lindblom, C. (1959). The Science of Muddling Through. Public Administration Review, 19, 79–88.
Mason, D., & Kluegel, J. (Eds.). (2000). Marketing Democracy: Changing Opinion About Inequality and Politics in
East Central Europe. Lanham, MD: Rowman & Littleeld.
Milanovic, B. (2016). The Winners and Losers of Globalization. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Montambeault, F. (2015). The Politics of Local Participatory Democracy in Latin America : Institutions, Actors, and
Interactions. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Moore, M. (2013). Revenue Reform and Statebuilding in Anglophone Africa Brighton, U.K.: Institute of
Development Studies
Munro, N. (2017). Predictors of Support for State Social Welfare Provision in Russia and China. Europe-Asia
Studies, 69(1), 53–75.
Musgrave, R. A., & Musgrave, P. B. (1989). Public Finance in Theory and Practice (Fifth Edition). San Francisco:
McGraw Hill.
Naidu, S., Rodrik, D., & Zucman, G. (2019). Economics for Inclusive Prosperity: An Introduction (Research Brief).
Economists for Inclusive Prosperity.
National Audit Ofce. (2012). Managing Budgeting in Government. London: NAO.
National Audit Ofce. (2015). Spending Review. London: NAO.
National Audit Ofce. (2018). Improving Government’s Planning and Spending Framework. London: NAO.
O'Hagan, A., & Klatzer, E. (Eds.). (2018). Gender Budgeting in Europe: Developments and Challenges. New York:
Palgrave Macmillan US.
ODI. (forthcoming). Review of Public Financial Management Diagnostics for the Health Sector. London: ODI and
UNICEF.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
73
OECD. (2005). Modernising Government: The Way Forward. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2018). Economic Survey of Greece. Paris: OECD.
Ostry, J. D., Loungani, P., & Berg, A. (2019). Confronting Inequality: How Societies Can Choose Inclusive Growth
New York: Columbia University Press.
Panzer, J., Thomas, M. R., Peuker, A. R., Razlog, L., Prasad, A., Anderson, P. R. D., & Li, Y. (2015). Debt
Management Performance Assessment (DeMPA) Methodology. Washington DC: World Bank.
PEFA Secretariat. (2016). PEFA: Framework for Assessing Public Financial Management. Washington DC: PEFA
Secretariat. Retrieved from https://pefa.org/sites/default/les/PEFA%20Framework_English.pdf
PEFA Secretariat. (2018). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
PEFA Secretariat. (2019). PEFA Handbook Volume IV: Using PEFA to Support Public Financial Management
Improvement. Washington DC: PEFA.
Peixoto, T., & Sifry, M. L. (2017). Civic Tech in the Global South : Assessing Technology for the Public Good.
Washington DC: World Bank and Personal Democracy Press.
Piatti-Fünfkirchen, M., & Schneider, P. (2018). From Stumbling Block to Enabler: The Role of Public Financial
Management in Health Service Delivery in Tanzania and Zambia. Health Systems & Reform, 4(4), 336–45.
Presbitero, Andrea F., Ghura, D., Adedeji, O. S., & Njie, L. (2015). International Sovereign Bonds by Emerging
Markets and Developing Economies: Drivers of Issuance and Spreads. Washington DC: IMF.
Prime Minister's Ofce. (2019). PM Theresa May: We Will End UK Contribution to Climate Change by 2050
[Press release]. Retrieved from https://www.gov.uk/government/news/pm-theresa-may-we-will-end-uk-
contribution-to-climate-change-by-2050
Ricke, K. L., Moreno-Cruz, J. B., Schewe, J., Levermann, A., & Caldeira, K. (2016). Policy Thresholds in
Mitigation. Nature Geoscience, 9, 5–6.
Roberts, J. (2003). Poverty Reduction Outcomes in Education and Health: Public Expenditure and Aid. London:
ODI.
Robinson, M. (2013). Spending Reviews (Paper for the Annual Meeting of OECD Senior Budget Ofcials, 3-4 June
2013). Paper presented at the Working Party of Senior Budget Ofcials, Paris.
Robinson, M. (2016). Budget Reform before and after the Global Financial Crisis. OECD Journal on Budgeting,
2016(1), 29–63.
Rogoff, K. (2019). The Austerity Chronicles. Retrieved from https://www.project-syndicate.org/onpoint/the-
austerity-chronicles-by-kenneth-rogoff-2019-04?barrier=accesspaylog
Ross, M. L. (1999). The Political Economy of the Resource Curse. World Politics, 51, 297–322.
Rudiger, A. (2018). Fiscal Futures: Scenario Thinking for Fiscal Transparency and Accountability. Washington DC:
Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, the International Budget Partnership and the Transparency
and Accountability Initiative.
Scharfstein, D., & Stein, J. (1990). Herd Behavior and Investment. American Economic Review, 80(June), 465–79.
Schick, A. (1998a). A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (35116). Washington DC:
World Bank Institute.
Schick, A. (1998b). Why Most Developing Countries Should Not Try New Zealand's Reforms. World Bank Research
Observer (International), 13, 23–31.
Schick, A. (2013). Reections on Two Decades of Public Financial Management Reforms. In M. Cangiano, T. R.
Curristine, & M. Lazare (Eds.), Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture (pp. 21–78).
Washington DC: IMF.
Schumpeter, J. A. (1918). Die Krise Des Steuerstaates. Berlin: Graz, Leuschner & Lubensky.
Senge, P. (1990). The Fifth Discipline: The Art and Practice of the Learning Organization. London: Random House.
Simson, R. (2012). Following the Money: Examining the Evidence on ‘Pro-Poor Budgeting. London: ODI.
Tilly, C. (1992). Coercion, Capital and European States, AD 990–1992. Oxford: Blackwell Publishing.
Ubaldi, B. (2013). Open Government Data: Towards Empirical Analysis of Open Government Data Initiatives
(OECD Working Papers on Public Governance, No. 22). Paris: OECD.
United States House of Representatives (116th Congress). (2019). “Recognizing the Duty of the Federal
Government to Create a Green New Deal.” H.Res. 109 (February 7).
van der Weide, R., & Milanovic, B. (2014). Inequality Is Bad for Growth of the Poor (but Not for That of the Rich).
Washington DC: World Bank.
Vlaicu, R., Verhoeven, M., Grigoli, F., & Mills, Z. (2014). Multiyear Budgets and Fiscal Performance: Panel Data
Evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 111(C), 79–95.
74
Welham, B., Hart, T., Mustapha, S., & Hadley, S. (2017). Public Financial Management and Health Service
Delivery: Necessary, but Not Sufcient? London: ODI.
Welham, B., Krause, P., & Hedger, E. (2013). Linking PFM Dimensions to Development Priorities. London: ODI.
Wildavsky, A. (1992). The New Politics of the Budget Process. New York: Harper Collins.
Wilhelm, V., & Fiestas, I. (2005). Exploring the Link between Public Spending and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from
the 90s. Washington DC: World Bank Institute.
Williamson, T., & Canagarajah, S. (2006). Pro-Poor Public Spending Reform : Uganda's Virtual Poverty Fund
(PREM Notes No. 108). Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2012a). Beyond the Annual Budget: Global Experience with Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks.
Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2012b). The World Bank’s Approach to Public Sector Management 2011–2020: Better Results from
Public Sector Institutions. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2014a). Climate Change Public Expenditure and Institutional Review Sourcebook. Washington DC:
World Bank.
World Bank. (2014b). Moving toward Climate Budgeting: Policy Note. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2016). PFM in Health – Conceptual Framework (Unpublished Draft Report). Washington DC.
References for Chapter 5
Andrews, M. (2013). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Andrews, M., Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2012). Escaping Capability Traps through Problem-Driven Iterative
Adaptation (PDIA) (Working Paper 299). Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Barder, O. (2018). Aid in the National Interest: When is Development Cooperation Win-Win? Retrieved from
https://www.cgdev.org/blog/aid-national-interest-when-development-cooperation-win-win
Birdsall, N. (2013). The Future of Aid: 2030 ODA No More. In A. Sumner & T. Kirk (Eds.), The Donors’ Dilemma:
Emergence, Convergence and the Future of Foreign Aid. Chichester, UK: Wiley.
Blum, J. R., Manning, N., & Srivastava, V. (2012). Public Sector Management Reform: Toward a Problem-
Solving Approach. Washington DC: World Bank. Retrieved from http://siteresources.worldbank.org/
EXTPREMNET/Resources/EP100.pdf
Booth, D. (2014). Aiding Institutional Reform in Developing Countries: Lessons from the Philippines on What
Works, What Doesn't, and Why. London: ODI.
Booth, D., & Unsworth, S. (2014). Politically Smart, Locally Led Development. London: ODI.
PEFA Secretariat. (2018). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
Gupta, S. and Barroy, H. (2020). The COVID-19 Crisis and Budgetary Space for Health in Developing Countries.
Retrieved from https://www.cgdev.org/blog/covid-19-crisis-and-budgetary-space-health-developing-
countries
Gurazada, S., Kristensen, J., Sjoblom, M., Piatti, M. and Farooq, K. (2020). Getting government nancial
management systems COVID-19 ready. Retrieved from https://blogs.worldbank.org/governance/getting-
government-nancial-management-systems-covid-19-ready
Saxena, S. and Stone, S. (2020). Preparing Public Financial Management Systems to Meet Covid-19 Challenges.
Retrieved from https://blog-pfm.imf.org/pfmblog/2020/03/preparing-public-nancial-management-
systems-to-meet-covid-19-challenges.html
World Bank. (2000). Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank Strategy.
Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2012b). The World Bank’s Approach to Public Sector Management 2011–2020: Better Results from
Public Sector Institutions. Washington DC: World Bank.
Chapter References
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
75
Annex A: Key concepts and terms
used in the report
This annex denes a number of the operative
terms and concepts used in this report. There are
very few settled denitions in the PFM literature,
and the intention is to explain and clarify the usage
in this report—not to join wider debates about
denitions or preferred usage.
For ease of explanation, four categories are used
here: public policy, scal policy, public nancial
management, and external assistance. Underlined
terms are those dened in Table 5 below.
1. Public policy: Public policy is a three-
level framework encompassing government
choices, actions, and results. Government
policy choices cover stated and revealed
intentions and objectives. Government
actions and outputs are policy choices being
put into action, including service delivery
(or the provision of collective goods and
services). Development results (including
sector outcomes) are the policy impacts that
stem from government choices and actions,
or lack thereof (see also Annex B).
2. Fiscal policy: Fiscal policy covers
government public nance policies. It is
characterized by scal policy norms that
inuence strategy and choices. The norms
are often expressed or observed through
scal rules of different types (such as
numerical limits on budgetary aggregates).
Choices about scal rules also feed back into
scal policy norms.
3. Public nancial management: The standard
PFM objectives dene the purpose of PFM.
The PFM system in a country consists of all
of its separate PFM processes and how they
t or work together. The PFM conventions
are the orthodoxy about how each of the
individual PFM processes should look or
perform. The PFM assessment frameworks
measure the performance of individual
PFM processes against the prevailing
PFM conventions. The PFM discipline
is the professional guild of experts and
practitioners who work in the eld of PFM.
4. External assistance: The intervention logic
explains the design assumptions about how/
why the intervention is expected to work.
Development assistance modalities are the
mechanisms or instruments through which
external support is provided. Problem-
based and adaptive approaches are a way
of attempting to ensure that the intervention
logic is not prescriptive and that the
assistance modalities are not rigid.
ANNEXES
76
Table 5: Terms of art used in the report
Term of art Denion Examples (if applicable)
A. Public policy (see also Annex B)
Public policy Anythingagovernmentchoosestodoornotto
do”(Dye,1972,p.2).
“Publicpolicy-makinginvolvesafundamental
choice[thatisdeliberateandconscious]onthe
partofgovernmentstodosomethingortodo
nothingwithrespecttoaproblem”(Howle&
Cashore,2014,p.18).
Representedbyathree-levelframework
comprising:governmentintenonsorpolicy
choices,governmentaconsandoutputs,and
policyimpacts(or,morenarrowly,development
results).(Seealsoseparatedenions.)
Government
policy
choices
“Decisionsmadebypolicians,civilservants,
orothersgrantedauthoritythataredirected
towardsusingpublicpowertoaectthelivesof
cizens”(Peters,2018,p.4).
Agovernmentsintenonsanddecisions.These
includebothpolicychoicesexplicitlystatedby
government,andthoserevealedimplicitlyby
governmentacons.
Improvedprosperity,well-being,equity,and
sustainability—asexpressed,forexample,
throughspeciccommitmentsonpublic
servicesandpublicmanagement,on
regulaonofeconomicbehavior,andon
responsestoachangingmacroenvironment.
Government
acons
“Policychoicesbeingputintoacon”(Peters,
2018,p.4).
Governmentaconscovereconomicinstruments
(includingpublicservicesandnancial
incenves),regulatoryinstruments,informaon
instruments,andadministravemeasures.
Provisionofpublicservices,cashtransfers,
regulaon,informaoncampaigns,
budgetsystemreforms,humanresource
managementreforms,andsoon.
Service
delivery
Servicedeliveryencompassestherangeof
collecvegoodsandserviceswithinthesphere
ofgovernmentacon.Thesegoodsandservices
areeitherprovidedbygovernmentthroughthe
budget,orfallundertheremitofgovernment
producon,subsidy,orregulaon(Hughes,2018).
Servicedeliveryisasubsetofgovernmentacons
takentoimplementitspublicpolicyintenons,
typicallywithanemphasisongovernment
provisionanditsoutputs.
Collecvegoodsandservicesinclude
educaon,lawandorder,environmental
protecon,naonaldefense,roadsand
bridges,hospitalsandhealthcare,welfare
services,publictransport,andsoon.
Development
results
Theeectsthatpolicychoicesandpolicy
outputshaveoncizens”(Peters,2018,p.4).
Abroadcategorycoveringtheimpactsof
governmentpolicychoicesandacons(see
separatedenions).Forthepurposesof
thisreport,itisrestrictedtothesubsetof
policyimpactswithwhichtheinternaonal
developmentcommunityistypicallymost
concernedandwhicharetreatedasdesirable
developmentoutcomes.
Themostgenerallyusedandaccepted
contemporaryformulaonofdevelopment
resultsisthe2030AgendaforSustainable
Development:
• “Endingpovertyandotherdeprivaons
mustgohand-in-handwithstrategiesthat
improvehealthandeducaon,reduce
inequality,andspureconomicgrowth—all
whiletacklingclimatechangeandworking
topreserveouroceansandforests”
(UnitedNaons,2015).
Annex A: Key concepts and terms used in the report
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
77
Term of art Denion Examples (if applicable)
Adisnconmaybedrawnbetween
intermediateresultssuchastheoutputs
fromservicedeliverybygovernment,andthe
outcomesinsectorstowhichthatservicedelivery
hascontributed.
Developmentresultsextendbeyondafocuson
sectorstocovergovernanceissues,including
scalandinstuonalsustainability(Kaufmann,
Kraay&Mastruzzi,2010).
B. Fiscal policy
Fiscal policy Measuresemployedbygovernmentstostabilize
theeconomy,specicallybymanipulangthe
levelsandallocaonsoftaxesandgovernment
expenditures.
Fiscal policy
norms
Theorthodoxiesthatgovern,determine,or
constrainpublicnancepolicyaconsand
parameters.Theyarealsothenormave
assumponsthatinformandinuenceexternal
ideasandadviceaboutsuitablepolicydirecons
andstrategy.
Theyareoenformallycodiedas“scalrules”
thatfocusonscaldisciplineandsustainability.
Fiscal rules Ascalruleisalong-lasngconstraintonscal
policythroughnumericallimitsonbudgetary
aggregates”(Lledó,Yoon,Fang,Mbaye&Kim,
2017,p.8).
Typesofscalrulesincludebudgetbalance
rules,debtrules,expenditurerules,andrevenue
rules—applyingtothecentralorgeneral
governmentorthepublicsector(Eyraud,Debrun,
Hodge,Lledo&Pallo,2018;Lledóetal.,2017).
Examplesofscalrules:
• “EUMemberStatesareconstrainedbythe
rulesoftheStabilityandGrowthPact.This
includesarequirementtokeepborrowing
below3%ofGDP.
• Structuralborrowing(borrowingadjusted
fortheupsanddownsoftheeconomy)
oftheGermanfederalgovernmentis
cappedat0.35%ofGDPinthecountrys
constuon.Germanyalsohastargetsfor
theLänders(states)”(Keep&Ward,2019,
pp.3–4).
C. Public nancial management
Standard
PFM
objecves
Thestated“desirableoutcomes”ofaPFM
system,reecnganormaveorientaonto
parcularobjecvesthathavebecomethe
orthodoxyoverthepast20–25years(Campos
&Pradhan,1996;Schick,1998;WorldBank,
1998).Theseareineecta“holytrinity”ofPFM
objecves:scaldiscipline,allocaveeciency,
andoperaonaleciency.
ThestandardPFMobjecvesmaybe
describedasfollows:
Aggregatescaldisciplinerequires
eecvecontrolofthetotalbudgetand
managementofscalrisks.
Strategicallocaonofresources involves
planningandexecungthebudgetin
linewithgovernmentprioriesaimedat
achievingpolicyobjecves.
Ecientservicedeliveryrequiresusing
budgetedrevenuestoachievethebest
levelsofpublicserviceswithinavailable
resources”(PEFASecretariat,2016,p.2).
78
Term of art Denion Examples (if applicable)
PFM system TheamalgamofallPFMprocessesand
proceduresinaparcularjurisdicon.
Ineect,thesearetheinstuonalarrangements
forPFMandhowitoperatesinagivencountry
(orsubnaonaldomain).“PFMisnowseenasan
‘umbrella’denion,coveringasetofsystems
aimedatproducinginformaon,processes,and
rules…”(Cangianoetal.,2013,pp.1–2).
PFM
processes
The technical elements or components of the
PFMsystem.
Thesearenotinandofthemselvesnormave
proposions,unlikethePFMconvenons(see
separatedenion).Theyaretechnicalbuilding
blocksaboutwhichdesignchoicescanbemade.
Budgetcalendar,scalstrategypaper,
nancialstatements,auditreport,budget
hearings,cash-owforecast,payrollrecords,
procurementmethod,andsoon.
PFM
assessment
frameworks
(or tools)
The“toolsavailableforassessingPFMsystems
asabasisfordevelopingandmonitoringreform
plansandthusstrengtheningPFMprocesses”
(PEFASecretariat,2018,p.1).
Theseframeworksandtoolsnotonlycapture
the PFM processes that comprise the overall
PFMsystem,theyalsoreecttheprevailing
convenons”aboutthedesirableoperaonal
performanceofthePFMsystem(seeseparate
denion).
PEFA,TADAT,DeMPA,PIMA,OpenBudget
Index,FiscalTransparencyCode,andothers
(AnnexF).
PFM
convenons
Thenormaveassumponsaboutdesirable
operaonalperformanceofkeyelementsofthe
PFMsystem”basedon“internaonalstandards
andgoodpraccesoncrucialaspectsofPFM,
asidenedbyexperiencedpraconers”and
asexpressedinthestandardPFMassessment
frameworksandtools(PEFASecretariat,2016,pp.
1–4).
Theframeworkstypicallyincludegraduated
performancescores,sotheconvenons
representatargengofthehighestscores.
Thereisanormaveassumponthatastronger
andmorecapablePFMsystemisoneinwhich
processesandproceduresfulllrequirementsat
thetopendofthemeasuredscales.
Generallyspeaking,thePFMconvenonscanbe
seeninthedescriponsofkeyelementsofthe
PFMsystemthatgarnerthehighestscoreinthe
variousassessmentframeworks.
Systemforallocangtransfers(PEFA
dimension7.1)
• AnAscore=“Thehorizontalallocaonof
alltransferstosubnaonalgovernments
fromcentralgovernmentisdetermined
bytransparent,rule-basedsystems”(PEFA
Secretariat,2016,p.26).
Performanceevaluaonforservicedelivery
(PEFAdimension8.4)
• AnAscore=“Independentevaluaons
oftheeciencyandeecvenessof
servicedeliveryhavebeencarriedout
andpublishedformost ministries at least
oncewithinthelastthreeyears”(PEFA
Secretariat,2016,p.28).
Countriesshouldhave:
• “Systemsforpublishinganannualplanof
aggregatedomescborrowingbasedon
theannualbudgetcashowforecasts
• Systemsforpublishingaborrowing
calendarinadvanceforwholesale
instruments”(Panzeretal.,2015,p.38).
Annex A: Key concepts and terms used in the report
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
79
Term of art Denion Examples (if applicable)
PFM
discipline
Aprofessionaldisciplinecombiningacademic
subjectmaerwithcareerpathsthatinclude
opportuniesforadvancementinworkand
reputaon.
A“sociologyofcareerincenves,normsand
socializaonpaerns”(Naiduet.al,2019,p.1).
D. External assistance
Intervenon
logic
(intervenon
design)
Severaloverlappingquesonsaregenerally
consideredexplicitlyor,moreoen,implicitly,in
thedesignofexternalintervenons:
• Thedegreetowhichitisassumedthatthe
speciedinput(training,newprocedures)will
leadinalinearfashiontotheintendedoutput
andoutcomeassetoutinaresultschain
(OECD,2017),logframe(DFID,2009;Team
Technologies,2005)orequivalent.
• Whetherthetheoryofchangesuggests
uncertaintyabouttheconsequencesofany
intervenonandtheneedforexibilityand
parcipaonbylocalactors(Valters,2015)and
henceemphasizestheneedforiteraonand
adaptaon.
• Whetherincenvestoachieveaspecied
outcomecouldbecombinedwithexibility
concerningthechoiceofinput(Birdsall&
Savedo,2010).Examplesofintervenontypes
thatfollowapureoutcome-basedlogicinclude
cashondelivery”aidanddevelopmentimpact
bonds.
• Quesonsaboutthetechnicalsequencingof
theproposedPFMcontent(Diamond,2013).
TheNaonalAssemblyofZambia
component operates on the demand side
ofPFM.Itseekstoimprovetheprocesses
ofaccountabilityandtransparencyby
strengtheningtheabilityandcapacityofthe
legislaturetoholdtheExecuveresponsible
foritsplansandacons.Strengtheningthe
demandforbeerPFM,includinggreater
accountabilityandtransparency,isseenas
aneecvemechanismforencouraging
improvedperformance”(DFCConsorum,
2016,p.67).
Development
assistance
modalies
(or
instruments)
Theformalstructuresofintervenonthrough
whichPFMideasandknowledgearedeployedor
deliveredtoclients/beneciaries(byinternaonal
organizaons,donorgovernments,consulng
rms,non-protorganizaons,individual
advisers,andsoon).
Thiscoversdesign,implementaon,and
evaluaonstagesofsupport,asapplicable.
Dierentcomponentsorinstrumentsmaybe
bundledtogetheraspartofasingleintervenon.
Technicalassistancemissionsorprojects,
investmentprojects,nancialsupport
throughgovernmentsystems(including
generalbudgetsupportandsectorbudget
support),pooledfunds,policyorstructural
reformcondions,results-basedfunding
(suchascashondeliveryandpaymentfor
results),andsoon.
80
Term of art Denion Examples (if applicable)
Problem-
based and
adapve
approaches
Techniquesforinvesgaon,dialogue,and
intervenon,which:
• Emphasizethelocally-speciccausesand
purposesofagivenapparentdysfuncon
(Andrewsetal.,2012)
• Assertthatinstuonalreformsareaddressing
“adapve”ratherthan“technical”problems
(Heifetz,1994,p.121)
• Emphasizetrialanderrorthrough“guided
incrementalexperimentaon”(Pritcheetal.,
2013,p.48).
“Problem-DrivenIteraveAdaptaon”
(Andrewsetal.,2012).
Flexibleprocesses(Brinkerho&Crosby,
2002;Brinkerho&Ingle,1989).
Tryingout”newapproachestobudgeng,
accounng,procurement,andsoon,in
nanceministriesforalimitednumberof
agenciesforalimitedperiodofmetotest
howthingswork(Kristensen,2019;CID,
2014).
References
Andrews, M., Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2012). Escaping Capability Traps through Problem-Driven Iterative
Adaptation (PDIA) (Working Paper 299). Cambridge MA: Harvard Kennedy School.
Birdsall, N., & Savedoff, W. D. (2010). Cash on Delivery: A New Approach to Foreign Aid. Washington DC: Center
for Global Development.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Crosby, B. L. (2002). Managing Policy Reform. Bloomeld CT: Kumarian.
Brinkerhoff, D. W., & Ingle, M. D. (1989). Integrating Blueprint and Process: A Structured Flexibility Approach to
Development Management. Public Administration and Development, 9, 487–503.
Campos, E., & Pradhan, S. (1996). Budgetary Institutions and Expenditure Outcomes (Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1646). Washington DC: World Bank.
Cangiano, M., Curristine, T., & Lazare, M. (2013). Introduction. In M. Cangiano, T. R. Curristine, & M. Lazare
(Eds.), Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture (pp. 1–20). Washington DC: IMF.
Center for International Development (CID) at Harvard University, Building State Capability Program. (2014). The
DDD Manifesto. ‘Doing Development Differently’ workshop. Retrieved from http://buildingstatecapability.
com/the-ddd-manifesto/
DFID. (2009). Guidance on Using the Revised Logical Framework London: DFID. Retrieved from http://www.dd.
gov.uk/Documents/publications1/how-to-guid-rev-log-fmwk.pdf
DFC Consortium. (2016). EU-Funded Programme in Zambia: Mid-Term Evaluation of the PFM Support
Programme. Brussels: EU.
Diamond, J. (2013). Good Practice Note on Sequencing PFM Reforms. Washington DC: PEFA Secretariat.
Dye, Thomas R. (1972). Understanding Public Policy. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.
Eyraud, L., Debrun, X., Hodge, A., Lledó, V. D., & Pattillo, C. A. (2018). Second-Generation Fiscal Rules :
Balancing Simplicity, Flexibility, and Enforceability. Washington DC: IMF.
Government of New Zealand. (2019). The Wellbeing Budget. Wellington, New Zealand: Department of the Prime
Minister and Cabinet.
Heifetz, R. A. (1994). Leadership without Easy Answers. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Howlett, M., & Cashore, B. (2014). Conceptualizing Public Policy. In I. Engeli & Allison C.R. (eds), Comparative
Policy Studies. Research Methods Series. London: Palgrave Macmillan.
Hughes, O. (2018). Public Management and Administration: An Introduction (5th Edition). London: Palgrave.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and
Analytical Issues. Washington DC: World Bank.
Keep, M., & Ward, M. (2019). Balanced Budget Rule. London: House of Commons Library.
Kristensen, J. K. (2019, February 28, 2019). [Email].
Lledó, V., Yoon, S., Fang, X., Mbaye, S., & Kim, Y. (2017). Fiscal Rules at a Glance. Washington DC: IMF.
Naidu, S., Rodrik, D., & Zucman, G. (2019). Economics for Inclusive Prosperity: An Introduction (Research Brief).
Economists for Inclusive Prosperity.
New Economics Foundation. (2012). Measuring Wellbeing: A guide for practitioners. London: New Economics
Foundation.
Annex A: Key concepts and terms used in the report
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
81
OECD. (2017). Strengthening the Results Chain: Synthesis of Case Studies of Results-Based Management by
Providers. Paris: OECD DAC.
Panzer, J., Thomas, M. R., Peuker, A. R., Razlog, L., Prasad, A., Anderson, P. R. D., & Li, Y. (2015). Debt
Management Performance Assessment (DeMPA) Methodology. Washington DC: World Bank.
PEFA Secretariat. (2016). PEFA: Framework for Assessing Public Financial Management. Washington DC: PEFA
Secretariat. Retrieved from https://pefa.org/sites/default/les/PEFA%20Framework_English.pdf
PEFA Secretariat. (2018). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
Peters, B. G. (2018). American Public Policy: Promise and Performance. New York: Sage.
Pritchett, L., Samji, S. & Hammer, J. (2013). It's All About MeE: Using Structured Experiential Learning ("E") to
Crawl the Design Space. Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Schick, A. (1998). A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (35116). Washington DC: World
Bank Institute.
Team Technologies. (2005). The Log Frame Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
United Nations. 2015. Sustainable Development Goals. Retrieved from https://sustainabledevelopment.un.org/sdgs
Valters, C. (2015). Theories of Change: Time for a Radical Approach to Learning in Development. London: ODI.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
82
Annex B: A framework for public
policy—government policy
choices, government actions, and
development results
A central proposition of the Working Group is
the need to ensure that there is an explicit and
dynamic connection between PFM and public
policy. While this report offers a reappraisal of the
scope and objectives of PFM, we do not attempt a
comparable assessment of public policy as a topic.
Instead we invoke well-established denitions and
frameworks from the public policy literature to
organize the arguments of the report.
This annex provides a description and explanation
of the framework for public policy that is adopted
by the Working Group. In particular, it highlights
some of central concepts used in this report—
namely, “policy choices,” “service delivery,”
and “development results”—and it locates those
within the framework. Recognizing that there is
no consensus on the terminology and concepts
discussed here, our purpose is not to suggest any
sort of general resolution, but rather to provide
a readers’ guide to the particular usage in the
present report. Annex A on key terms, and Annex
H on results chains, provide additional and
complementary background.
Public policy as choices, actions, and
results
Articulating the chain of connections between
intentions and outcomes, beyond broad
generalities, is challenging. To start with, there are
few settled denitions of what constitutes public
policy. Peters (2018) captures the ambiguity well:
“Samuel Johnson once commented that patriotism
is the last refuge of fools and scoundrels. To some
degree, public policy has become just such a
refuge for some academic disciplines” (p. 4).
As a starting point, it is necessary to note that
public policy is not merely a list of government
intentions. “Policy is both the plan and the ensuing
course of action” (Biggs & Helms, 2007, p. 7).
Accordingly, Peters (2018, p. 4) identies three
levels of public policy:
Government policy choices, comprising
“decisions made by politicians, civil servants
or others granted authority that are directed
towards using public power to affect the lives of
citizens.”
Government policy outputs or “policy choices
being put into action.”
Policy impacts or “the effects that policy choices
and policy outputs have on citizens.”
We adopt these three levels as our framework in the
report. We re-label them slightly as “government
policy choices,” “government actions,” and
“development results.” One important departure
from Peters (2018), however, is that we focus on
development results as a narrower category than
policy impacts—covering the subset of policy
impacts with which the international development
community is typically most concerned and which
are captured in global normative frameworks such
as the SDGs.
Even with an agreed disaggregation and taxonomy,
there remains substantive difculty in interpreting
the relationships between the three levels of
public policy. These links between government
policy choices (in the sense of what governments
say—or even don’t say—they want to do),
government actions, and the observed policy
impacts (incorporating development results) are
not automatic, linear, or unidirectional. Moreover,
the literature on policy reform in developing
countries largely avoids this question by focusing
instead on normative policy proposals or on the
political economy of adopting those proposals
(Jones, 2009).
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
83
Figure 4 depicts the full framework for public
policy—government policy choices (A),
government actions (B), and development results
(C)—used in the Working Group report, along
with some illustrative content. We briey explain
each of the “public policy” levels in turn, agging
some pointers and caveats about the interactions
between the three dimensions.
Figure 4: Links and interactions between the dimensions of public policy
Government policy choices (A)
Government policy intentions to underpin improved prosperity, well-being, equity, and sustainability, such as:
• Regulation of economic behavior (enabling environment policies, industrial strategy, and so on)
Managing responses to changing macro environment (fiscal policy, monetary policy, investment policy, structural reforms,
and so on)
• Priorities in public services (sector policies) and administrative arrangements (institutional design)
Policy as explicitly stated by government Policy as revealed by government actions
Government actions (B)
Economicinstruments,parallycoveredby: Regulatoryinstruments
(“measures
undertaken…to
inuencepeopleby
meansofformulated
rulesanddirecves”
(Vedung,2007,p.31))
Informaon
instruments
(persuasionwithout
“materialresourcesor
obligatorydirecves”
(Vedung,2007,p.31))
Administrave
measures(“budgeng,
managementand
accountability
approaches”(Manning
andLau,2015,p.42),
suchasintroduconof
anMTEFornewhiring
procedures)
Publicservices(or
“servicedelivery”)
(servicesfunded
throughgovernment
spending,either
commissioned or
directlyprovided)
Financialincenves
(taxexpenditures,
cashtransfers,loans
andloanguarantees,
governmentinsurance
andgrants,andso
on)
Development results (within wider policy impacts) (C)
Sectorandcross-cungoutcomes,andcizensasfacon,parally
measuredby:
Governanceandinstuonaloutcomes,parally
measuredby:
• Fiscalandinstuonalsustainability
• Voiceandaccountability
• Policalstabilityandabsenceofviolence
• Regulatoryquality
• Ruleoflaw
• Controlofcorrupon
Sector-specic
outcomes
(forexample,progress
onindicatorsofSDGs
onhealth,educaon,
sanitaon,hunger,
climate)
Cross-cungoutcomes
(compositemeasures
ofcizenwell-being,
equity,prosperity,
sustainability,andso
on)
Cizensasfacon
(compositemeasures
ofcizensasfacon
withpublicservices,
governmentintegrity,
andsoon)
Source:Authors’compilaon,drawingprincipallyonKaufmannetal.(2010),ManningandLau(2015),Peters(2018),Vedung
(2007),andWorldBank(2012b).
Government acons reveal
implicit policy choices (α)
Government acons lead to policy impacts,
and ideally to development results
Policy changes or policy iniaves
lead to government acons
Policy impacts are the
primary signal of eecve
government acons (β)
84
Government policy choices (A)
Government policy choices are a compound of
government’s stated intentions and objectives
on the one hand (Evans & Manning, 2003) and,
on the other, its policy as revealed de facto by
its actions (Glismann & Horn, 1988; Skrbinjek,
Šušteršic & Lesjak, 2018, pp.168-186; Stolper,
1972). The rst level in Figure 4 shows these
policy choices (A), which will underpin objectives
such as improved prosperity, well-being, equity,
and sustainability—and which may be expressed
through specic commitments or proposals
about priorities in public services and public
management, regulation of economic behavior,
and responses to a changing macro environment.
Policy choices can be seen both in what a
government says it is going to do and in what it
actually does. The feedback loop (α) in Figure 4
shows that interaction. For example, a government
that states it will improve maternal health care
for rural villages, and then does it, is showing its
stated intentions and its actions. A government
that allows teacher absenteeism to go unchecked
may be revealing that its policy includes deferring
to a powerful voting bloc (Keefer & Vishwanath,
2003). Administrative measures, such as reforms
in PFM or human resources management, may
also create a feedback loop from government
actions to government policy choices. They may
affect or reveal policy choices, even if those effects
are unintended. For example, the introduction of
an MTEF or a change in senior staff employment
contracts may serve, respectively, to introduce
inertia into policy change (Schick, 2013) or to
increase loyalty to political principals (Pollitt,
2015).
Added to the challenge of discerning a
government’s policy choices, the stated policy
objectives may be closer to a political façade than
a genuine government commitment to provide the
resources and authority needed for the stated policy
to be implemented in a meaningful way (Rakner,
Mukubvu, Ngwira, Smiddy & Schneider, 2004;
Sabatier & Weible, 2014). Many policy statements
are concerned with political positioning and
agenda setting rather than with forming a reliable
indication of a government’s intentions. Examples
range from the Armenian “economic program”
introduced to parliament by the Prime Minister
in February 2019, to the annual “US Economic
Report of the President,” to the (typically) annual
“Queen’s Speech” to Parliament in the United
Kingdom (and its equivalent, the “Speech from the
Throne,” in Canada), to the National Development
Plans that have been prepared and published by
134 countries. In those National Development
Plans the costing of policy choices and associated
nancing plan are often “the weakest element”
(Chimhowua, Hulme & Munroc, 2019, p. 83).
More specic and, arguably, reliable government
policy commitments are set out in budget
documentation—as proposed by the executive
and approved by the legislature. Shapiro (2001)
notes that the “budget is the most important
economic policy instrument for governments.
It reects a government’s social and economic
policy priorities more than any other document,
translating policies, political commitments, and
goals into decisions on where funds should be
spent and how funds should be collected” (pp.
6–7).
In a development cooperation setting, there is
the additional complication that there may not be
alignment between the preferences and priorities
of a government on the one hand and development
assistance providers on the other. “Country
ownership” is often assumed or invoked without
sufciently careful consideration or foundation
(Booth, 2011). Government incentives to provide
private goods may conict with donors’ concerns
for the provision of broad-based public services
in sectors such as health and education (Keefer &
Khemani, 2003; Khemani, 2017). These tensions
or mismatches in preference give further weight to
the argument that government policy choices are
often revealed by what gets done as much as by
what was promised.
Annex B: A framework for public policy
Government policy choices, government actions, and development results
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
85
Government actions (B)
Government actions are “policy instruments…
[which are] concrete and specied operational
forms of intervention by public authorities”
(Bemelmans-Videc, 2007, p. xi). Such actions
may or may not be taken as a result of government
policy and it is those actions, not the intentions,
that may (or, again, may not) contribute to
development results. The second level in Figure
4 shows these government actions (B), which
consist of economic instruments (including public
services and nancial incentives), regulatory
instruments, and information instruments.
1
As
shown in the framework, administrative measures
could be considered an additional category of
government actions in response to policy changes
(Manning & Lau, 2015).
Using economic instruments—comprising
either public services or nancial incentives—to
implement government policy choices involves
“the handing out or the taking away of material
resources, be they in cash or in kind” which “make
it cheaper or more expensive in terms of money,
time, effort or other valuables to pursue certain
actions” (Vedung, 2007, p. 10).
Public services involve budgetary actions by
the government related to collective goods and
services (Hughes, 2018), especially in sectors—
such as education, law and order, environmental
protection, national defense, roads and bridges,
hospitals and health care, welfare services, and
public transport. Government may provide these
public goods directly through its own agencies
and staff, or it may commission them through
non-state actors,
2
or it may only fund them
through transfer of resources (Biggs & Helms,
2007). Table 6 presents a more detailed analysis
of the options available to government concerning
public services.
In the context of development cooperation in
lower-income countries, the language of “service
delivery” is used regularly and has become a
prominent focus for many development assistance
providers. Figure 5 shows the rising number
of references to service delivery in relation to
development assistance in publications between
1960 and 2005. In line with this emphasis and
trend, this report examines more specically the
relationship between PFM and service delivery,
as one critical element of government actions
through its economic instruments.
Figure 5: Ngram plot of references in literature published in English containing
the terms “service delivery” and “development assistance”
Year of publication
Relative frequency of “service delivery” and
development assistance” in published literature
86
A complication arises when assessing government
actions concerning public services. To make
a credible claim that service delivery has
“improved,” there must have been a signicant
downstream contribution to development results,
especially in terms of related sector or cross-
cutting outcomes. The quality of an output, or
service, is ultimately a measure of “the attributable
incremental contribution of the service to the
outcome” (Atkinson et al., 2005, p. 42).
3
In other
words, policy impacts are the primary signal of
effective government actions. The feedback loop
(β) in Figure 4 shows this interaction.
As an alternative to public services, a government
can use nancial incentives to inuence individuals
and rms to adopt particular behaviors. These
incentives may consist of tax expenditures, cash
transfers, loans and loan guarantees, government
insurance and grants, and so on. This instrument,
in essence, involves a specic cash-based offering
(or levy) from government that leaves individuals
and rms with options about their behaviors—
albeit with potential penalties for making the
wrong choice.
Alongside economic instruments, there are other
actions that governments can take in relation
to their policy choices. Either they can mandate
actions to be taken or not taken by individuals
and rms through regulation, or they can provide
information with the aim of changing views on
why particular actions should be preferred. In
contrast to funded or taxable options implemented
through economic instruments, these actions
do not involve the ow of funds as the primary
mechanism.
4
Regulatory instruments are “measures
undertaken…to inuence people by means of
formulated rules and directives” (Vedung, 2007,
p. 31). These can, of course, have a public service
intention if they affect how market and non-prot
providers deliver services that specic groups are
able to receive (Biggs & Helms, 2007).
The information instrument “covers attempts
at inuencing people through the transfer of
knowledge, the communication of reasoned
argument, and persuasion,” in which “the
absence of obligation makes information different
from regulation which, by denition, contains
mandatory rules of conduct” (Vedung, 2007, pp.
11–13). It does not involve “material resources or
obligatory directives” (Vedung, 2007, p. 31).
Development results (C)
Development results are the subset of potential
policy impacts that are of greatest concern to
the international development community. They
represent those policy impacts that are considered
to be critical for sustainable economic and social
development. The third level in Figure 4 shows
these development results (C), which include
sector outcomes, cross-cutting outcomes, citizen
satisfaction, and governance and institutional
outcomes.
Development results at the sector level can
include progress toward desired outcomes in
health, education, sanitation, hunger, climate,
and so on. Cross-cutting outcomes may include
progress in areas such as citizen well-being,
equity, prosperity, and sustainability. These may
be viewed as composite objectives that draw on
outcomes across sectors. Related to these sector
and cross-cutting outcomes is the level of public
condence in and satisfaction with the quality
of public services, the degree of government
integrity, and so on. Development results can also
include, broadly, governance and institutional
outcomes as a distinct category. The scope of such
a category would include scal and institutional
sustainability, voice and accountability, political
stability and absence of violence, regulatory
quality, rule of law, and control of corruption
(Kaufmann et al., 2010).
We lay no claim to an authoritative typology of
development results here. In a domestic public
policy setting, conguring the framework for
capturing and assessing policy impacts rests with
government and civil society. At a global level, the
SDGs provide the most comprehensive and widely
accepted results framework. But the SDGs will
Annex B: A framework for public policy
Government policy choices, government actions, and development results
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
87
not necessarily align tightly with the way govern-
ments track the impacts of their policy choices and
actions. For example, governments often include
among their objectives strengthened security
forces, but consideration of policy impacts in the
defense and security sector is unlikely to feature
so strongly in the results frameworks used by
development assistance providers.
Peters (2018) offers a useful reminder that policy
impacts are “the effects that policy choices and
policy outputs have on citizens” (p. 4). There
can be a tension between what the development
community regards as policy priorities and what
an individual government considers it has to do
to manage domestic constituencies and real-
world pressures. The framework for public policy
presented in this annex does not suggest that the
latter should be made subject to the former, or
vice versa. It simply notes that, in considering the
development of public policy, both considerations
are prominent.
88
Table 6: Government actions for public services range from direct provision
to regulation
How transacons are recorded in the
system of naonal accounts (SNA)
Examples of agencies
responsible for a service
Government acons to ensure that services are
provided in line with government policy decisions
Administraveunitsingovernment Directproduconofservices
by ministries and departments
incentralgovernment
Directprovisionofservices,for
exampleteachinginstateschools
Direct
provision
Allnon-marketnon-protinstuons
thatarecontrolledandmorethan50
percentnancedbygovernmentunits
Schools,hospitals,andsimilar
instuonsthatarefunded
andcontrolledlargelyby
centralgovernmentbutnot
ownedbygovernment
Commissioningorfundingof
services,forexamplestatefunding
ofstudentplacesinreligiousschools
thatarealsorequiredtofollow
naonalcurriculaandstandards
Marketproducers,controlledby
government,sellinggoodsorservices
ataneconomicallysignicantprice
(“publicenterprises”),including
publicnancial(quasi-)corporaons
andpublicnon-nancial(quasi-)
corporaons,asdenedbyS.11and
S.12intheSNA
Publiclyownedbanks,publicly
ownedharbors,airports
Commissioningorfundingof
services,forexamplestatefundingof
sociallysignicantferryrouteswith
requirementsconcerningfrequency
Marketproducerswhoseindirect
publicfundingcomprisesmorethan
50percentoftotalrevenue,including
non-protandfor-protinstuons,
asdenedbyS.11,S.12intheSNA
For-protornon-protprivate
hospitalsaccessibletopublicly
insuredclients
Regulaonandcommissioningor
funding,forexampleregulaon
ofhospitalsconcerningprovision
ofcaretouninsuredpaentsand
reimbursementmechanisms
Non-protinstuonsserving
households,nancedmorethan
50percentbygovernment,butnot
controlledbygovernment,including
non-protinstuonsserving
households,asdenedbyS.15inthe
SNA
Schools,hospitals,andother
instuonsthatarefunded
largelybygovernmentbut
neitherownednorcontrolled
bygovernment
Regulaonandcommissioningor
funding,forexampleeducaon
vouchersandregulaonofschools
that can accept them
Privateenterpriseswithadisncve
andstatutorilyprivilegedmarket
posion,includingprivatesector
ulieslicensedtooperateinlimited
markets(suchaswater,energy,
sewage,wastedisposal,andpostal
services,butnottelecommunicaons)
andlegalmonopolies,asdenedby
S.11intheSNA
Energycompanies,localpublic
transportcompanies,naonal
train company
Regulaon,forexamplerequiring
minimumservicestandards
Marketproducersnotnancedor
controlledbygovernment
Private enterprises Regulaon,forexampleconcerning
transparency in sales of services
Non-protinstuonsserving
households,notnancedorcontrolled
bygovernment
Charies Regulaon,forexampleconcerning
equityintreatmentofapplicantsfor
assistance Regulaon
Note:SomeclassicaonsinthistableweredevelopedbyPilichowskiandTurkisch(2008).Thistableomitssocialsecurityfunds
ateachlevelofgovernment—forexample,ahealthfund,unemploymentfund,orpensionfund—whichareincludedintheSNA.
Annex B: A framework for public policy
Government policy choices, government actions, and development results
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
89
References
Atkinson, T., Grice, J., Simkins, A., Freitas, L. d., Hemingway, J., King, B., Lee, P., Lyon, M., Mai, N., Mehmi, S.,
Pritchard, A., Snelling, J., Tuke, A., Watson, L., & Fletcher-Cooke, G. (2005). Measurement of Government
Output and Productivity for the National Accounts. Basingstoke: Palgrave.
Bemelmans-Videc, M.-L. (2007). Policy Instrument Choice and Evaluation. In M.-L. Bemelmans-Videc, R. C. Rist,
& E. Vedung (Eds.), Carrots, Sticks and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation (pp. ix–xxiii).
New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.
Biggs, S., & Helms, L. B. (2007). The Practice of American Public Policymaking. Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
Booth, D. (2011). Aid Effectiveness: Bringing Country Ownership (and Politics) Back In. London: ODI.
Chimhowua, A. O., Hulme, D., & Munroc, L. T. (2019). The ‘New’ National Development Planning and Global
Development Goals: Processes and Partnerships. World Development, 120(August 2019), 76–89.
Evans, G., & Manning, N. (2003). Helping Governments Keep Their Promises: Making Ministers and Governments
More Reliable through Improved Policy Management. Washington DC: World Bank.
Glismann, H. H., & Horn, E.-J. (1988). International Arms Trade: Revealed Political Preferences or Cartel
Behaviour? Kiel, Germany: Institut für Weltwirtschaft.
Hughes, O. (2018). Public Management and Administration: An Introduction (5th Edition). London: Palgrave.
Jones, H. (2009). Policy-Making as Discourse: A Review of Recent Knowledge-to-Policy Literature. London: ODI.
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and
Analytical Issues. Washington DC: World Bank.
Keefer, P., & Khemani, S. (2003). Democracy, Public Expenditures, and the Poor. Washington DC: World Bank.
Keefer, P. E., & Vishwanath, A. N. T. (2003). The Political Economy of Decentralization in Pakistan. Washington
DC: World Bank.
Khemani, S. (2017). Political Economy of Reform. Washington DC: World Bank.
Manning, N. & Lau, E. (2015). “Public Management Reforms across OECD Countries.” In T. Bovaird and E. Löfer
(eds.) Public Management and Governance, London, Routledge, pp. 39–54.
OECD. (1997). Measuring Public Employment in OECD Countries: Sources, Methods and Results. Paris: OECD.
Peters, B. G. (2018). American Public Policy: Promise and Performance. New York: Sage.
Pilichowski, E., & Turkisch, E. (2008). Employment in Government in the Perspective of the Production Costs
of Goods and Services in the Public Domain. Paris: OECD. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/
dataoecd/33/51/40088862.pdf
Pollitt, C. (2015). “Public Servants to Public Managers: The European Story: Transformation or Torture?” 11th
Transatlantic Dialogue (TAD) 3-5 June. Boston, M.
Rakner, L., Mukubvu, L., Ngwira, N., Smiddy, K., & Schneider, A. (2004). The Budget as Theatre – the Formal and
Informal Institutional Makings of the Budget Process in Malawi. Bergen: Chr. Michelsen Institute.
Sabatier, P. A., & Weible, C. M. (2014). Theories of the Policy Process. New York: Avalon Publishing.
Schick, A. (2013). Reections on Two Decades of Public Financial Management Reforms. In M. Cangiano, T. R.
Curristine, & M. Lazare (Eds.), Public Financial Management and Its Emerging Architecture (pp. 21–78).
Washington DC: IMF.
Shapiro, I. (Ed.) (2001). A Guide to Budget Work for NGOs. Washington DC: International Budget Project, Center
on Budget and Policy Priorities.
Skrbinjek, V., Šušteršic, J., & Lesjak, D. (2018). Political Preferences and Public Funding of Tertiary Education
During the Economic Crisis. Tertiary Education and Management, 24(2).
Stolper, W. F. (1972). Budget, Economic Policy, and Economic Performance in Underdeveloped Countries.
Michigan: Center for Research on Economic Development, University of Michigan.
Sturgess, G. L. (2018). Public Service Commissioning: Origins, Inuences, and Characteristics. Policy Design and
Practice, 1(3), 155–68. doi:10.1080/25741292.2018.1473100
Vedung, E. (2007). Policy Instruments: Typologies and Theories. In M.-L. Bedelmans-Videc, R. C. Rist, & E.
Vedung (Eds.), Carrots, Sticks and Sermons: Policy Instruments and Their Evaluation (pp. 1–38). New
Brunswick: Transaction Publishers.
World Bank. (2012b). The World Bank’s Approach to Public Sector Management 2011–2020: Better Results from
Public Sector Institutions. Washington DC: World Bank.
90

management reforms in context
Technical reforms in how money, people, and
organizations are managed within the public
sector—and how risk is shared among the various
actors who are responsible for producing public
services—have been common in advanced and
developing economies over the last three decades.
The selections at a particular time in a particular
place might vary, but the overall menu (set out
below) is likely to be familiar to many public
managers.
Introducing new institutional options for managing
budgetary practices and compensation and careers
are the most well-known. Both of these areas have
been associated closely with the development of
performance metrics, generally for informational
purposes but with growing use of spending
reviews that draw on performance evaluations to
create scal space for higher-priority spending or
for decit reduction.
In many advanced economies, changes to
budgetary procedures since 2008 have also been
driven by scal consolidation in the wake of
economic downturn. Many recent developments
in the establishment of scal rules (for example,
numerical limits on budgetary aggregates),
bolstered by the creation of independent scal
institutions that provide independent analysis of
scal policy and long-term scal sustainability
and by the monitoring of compliance with scal
rules, were driven by consolidation experiences
(IMF, 2010; Lassen, 2010; OECD, 2010).
Table 7: Recent public sector reforms
Public sector domain Common reform measures and innovaons
Instuonal changes for budgeng and public nancial management
Budget pracces and
procedures
•Input-orientedlineitembudget—incrementalorwithsomeperformance
informaon
•Budgetproceduresandmingbasedaroundperformancerepornginthe
1990s
•Consideraonofaccrualsbudgeng
Use of scal rules (expenditure, budget balance, debt, and revenue) and
establishment of independent scal instuons
Medium-term perspecve in budget preparaon, top-down budgeng, and
budget exibility (for example, the carryover of unused funds)
Fiscal transparency
Accounng Cash-based
•Double-entrybookkeeping
Accrual accounng with extended cost calculaon supported by performance
measurement system
Audit •Tradionalnancialandcomplianceaudit
Value-for-money focus with elements of performance audit and evaluaon
Instuonal changes for human resource management in the public sector
Workforce size and
composion
•Incenvesforworkforcereducon
Strategic workforce planning
Greater use of lateral entry, parcularly for senior sta
Compensaon and careers •Movestowardaposion-basedsystem(oreventowardtheuseofageneral
laborlaw)
Decentralizaon of the employer and personnel management funcons
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
91
Public sector domain Common reform measures and innovaons
More explicit codes of conduct and codes of ethics
Limited introducon of performance-related pay
Moves toward dened-contribuon pension schemes
Creaon of senior civil service or equivalent
Instuonal changes for regulaon, service delivery, and intergovernmental relaons
Regulatory management Growth in independent regulators
Creaon of central bodies for regulatory management
Intergovernmental
decentralizaon
• Somefunconalandscaldecentralizaontosubnaonalgovernments
Organizaonal diversicaon Unbundling: creaon of “arm’s-length” agencies
Delegaon of managerial authority within central ministries and departments
Instuonal changes for sharing risks
Outsourcing and public
private partnerships
• Increasedoutsourcing
E-procurement
Use of public private partnerships at the expense of tradional infrastructure
procurement
Instuonal changes for empowering cizens
Market-based mechanisms Market-based approaches to delivering public services (including the
introducon of user charges and some use of vouchers)
Market-based approaches to delivering internal government services
Market-based approaches to seng regulatory standards or prices
Open government “Passive” openness: provision of informaon about services and entlements
through charters; freedom of informaon legislaon
Acve” openness: open government data; open services; open policy making,
cizen engagement, and user parcipaon
Extension of oces of ombudsman
E-government Integrated service delivery, in parcular through one-stop shops, based on
aligned infrastructure and legal frameworks
Shared back-oce services
Applicaons, data storage, and compung power through cloud compung
rather than publicly owned systems
Mobile government
Note:Itemsinitalicsarethosethathavebecomemoreprominentwithinthelastthreedecades.
Sources:ThisisdevelopedfromManning&Lau(2015)anddrawsonJoumard,Kongsrud,Nam&Price(2004);OECD(2005a,
2005b,2007,2009,2011,2013);andPolli&Bouckaert(2011).
References
IMF. (2010). Strategies for Fiscal Consolidation in the Post-Crisis World. Washington DC: IMF.
Joumard, I., Kongsrud, P. M., Nam, Y.-S., & Price, R. (2004). Enhancing the Cost Effectiveness of Public Spending:
Experience in OECD Countries. OECD Economic Studies, 2003/2(37), 109–61.
Lassen, D. D. (2010). Fiscal Consolidations in Advanced Industrialized Democracies: Economics, Politics, and
Governance. Copenhagen: University of Copenhagen.
Manning, N., & Lau, E. (2015). Public Management Reforms across OECD Countries. In T. Bovaird & E. Löfer
(Eds.), Public Management and Governance (pp. 39–54). London: Routledge.
OECD. (2005a). Modernising Government: The Way Forward. Paris: OECD.
92
OECD. (2005b). The OECD Human Resources Working Party: A Summary Retrospective and an Agenda for Action.
Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2007). Towards Better Measurement of Government (OECD Working Papers on Public Governance,
2007/1). Paris: OECD. Retrieved from http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/11/61/38134037.pdf
OECD. (2009). Government at a Glance. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2010). Fiscal Consolidation: Requirements, Timing, Instruments and Institutional Arrangements. Paris:
OECD.
OECD. (2011). Government at a Glance. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2013). Government at a Glance. Paris: OECD.
Pollitt, C., & Bouckaert, G. (2011). Public Management Reform: A Comparative Analysis (Third ed.). Oxford, UK:
Oxford University Press.
Annex C: Public nancial management reforms in context
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
93
Annex D: PFM focus within World
Bank sector activities
World Bank project data allows analysis of
activities by Global Practice (the World Bank’s
15 Global Practices map roughly to the “sector,”
or the part of the economy that the activity is
supporting)
1
and by theme (the specic purposes
of the support).
2
Theme taxonomies were changed
in 2017, so longer time series data are available
only before that date. Examining the proportion of
activities within a particular Global Practice that
contain signicant PFM thematic content
3
gives a
snapshot of the changing signicance of PFM as
a body of knowledge and area of concern within
that Global Practice.
The activities shown in the gures below
encompass all lending instruments (except those
that were closed before implementation) by year
of approval, including development policy loans,
investments, Program for Results, non-project
technical assistance, and other advisory services
and analytics.

Health, Nutrition, and Population Global Practice
Note:Theacviesincludedcontainatleast30%PFMthemacfocus.
Source:Authors’calculaonsfromWorldBankprojectdata.
94

Education Global Practice
Note:Theacviesincludedcontainatleast30%PFMthemacfocus.
Source:Authors’calculaonsfromWorldBankprojectdata.

Governance Global Practice
Note:Theacviesincludedcontainatleast30%PFMthemacfocus.
Source:Authors’calculaonsfromWorldBankprojectdata.
References
World Bank. (2016a). Sector Taxonomy and Denitions. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2016b). Theme Taxonomy and Denitions. Washington DC: World Bank.
Annex D: PFM focus within World Bank sector activities
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
95
Annex E: The quality of data on

Determining the size or impact of mainstream
donor inuence on PFM reform in client countries
remains a daunting challenge, constrained by
data weaknesses and denitional difculties
(AlphaBeta, 2018). Current measures of
development nancing for PFM stem largely
from OECD DAC data on ofcial development
assistance (ODA).
1
These data can be somewhat
problematic, but it is likely that accompanying
data on other ofcial ows (OOF) are even more
poorly captured (Hynes & Scott, 2013).
ODA captures ofcial aid from most major
providers, whether they are formal members of the
OECD’s DAC (such as the United States, United
Kingdom, France, and Germany) or have a reporting
relationship with DAC (including Russia, Turkey,
the United Arab Emirates, Kuwait, and Saudi
Arabia). Other donors do not currently report to
DAC (including China, Brazil, India, and Qatar).
ODA funds are channeled largely via multilateral
and regional development banks as well as
bilateral foreign affairs, nance, and development
ministries and agencies. Under the OECD’s
classication, Public Finance Management
(code 15111) is classied as part of the subgroup
Government and Civil Society (code 151). PFM
includes donors’ efforts to assist countries in scal
policy design and implementation, together with
more narrowly dened PFM reforms such as
revenue collection, expenditure management, and
public debt management. Currently available data
track annual nancial ows from DAC countries,
multilateral agencies, and regional development
banks from 2002 to 2016.
2
OOF data are recorded separately, recognizing
a proportion of loans at market or near-market
interest rates and bilateral export credits. OOFs
are largely loans for general development or scal
reforms, or other similar activities. Reported OOF
disbursements for PFM are widely thought to be
somewhat inated, with a signicant proportion
supporting scal policy reforms. It is estimated
that the proportion of OOF spent on PFM lies,
in reality, between 5 and 20 percent of what was
reported.
Other nancial ows are not captured in ODA or
OOF totals:
The IMF has noted that, in recent years, China
has become the largest single trading partner
for Africa and a key investor and provider of
aid. Moreover, China has become the largest
nancier of Africa’s infrastructure, accounting
for around one-third of total nancing. Chinese
banks have provided around US$ 132 billion in
nancing to Africa and Latin American countries
since 2003 (Bräutigam & Gallagher, 2014;
Evans, 2018; Gallagher, 2016; IMF, 2013; Lin &
Wang, 2017).
Besides China, new government funders of
development activities are emerging, with so-
called “non-traditional” development actors
(such as India and Turkey) growing in their
indirect inuence on the eld of PFM and on
PFM reform advice in lower-income countries.
Over the past 10 years, these (non-China)
emerging economies have become major
sources of international development nance,
infrastructure investment, and outward foreign
direct investment.
Some funding is provided by large-scale private
philanthropy, and this can be construed as quasi-
ofcial support. The Bill & Melinda Gates
Foundation, for example, now reports to DAC
and is increasingly deemed to hold de facto
ofcial status.
3
Total non-ODA, non-OOF nancing that is
provided for PFM is likely to be small (AlphaBeta,
2018). The picture may change, however, with
the development of measures of “total ofcial
support for sustainable development” (TOSSD)
as a complement to ODA. This new measure
may provide a clearer indication of the resources
invested to achieve sustainable development. It
is expected to encompass all nancing provided
by ofcial bilateral and multilateral institutions,
regardless of the level of concessionality involved
96
or the instrument used—whether grants, loans,
or other equity—and to include contributions to
global public goods. In sum, while current ODA
totals measure the grant equivalent of resource
ows, registering donor “effort” in making
resources available, the new measure will consider
the full face value of the ow (gross amounts),
thereby providing a fuller picture of resources
available to developing countries (Benn & Ibanez,
2018). As yet, we do not have estimates of the
likely differences that might be picked up by
the use of the TOSSD methodology (Delalande,
Rühmann, Bejraoui & Benn, 2019).
References
AlphaBeta. (2018). The Landscape of PFM Reform in Developing Countries: Trends in Financing and
Implementation of PFM Reforms over 2002–16. Singapore: AlphaBeta.
Benn, J., & Ibanez, M. B. (2018). Total Ofcial Support for Sustainable Development (TOSSD): TOSSD Task Force
Issues Paper. Paris: OECD.
Bräutigam, D., & Gallagher, K. P. (2014). Bartering Globalization: China's Commodity-Backed Finance in Africa
and Latin America. Global Policy, 5(3), 346–52.
Delalande, G., Rühmann, F., Bejraoui, A., & Benn, J. (2019). Nigeria’s Perspective on TOSSD. Paris: OECD DAC.
Evans, M. (2018). Chinese Lending for African Infrastructure Trebles, Led by Policy Banks. Retrieved from https://
www.bakermckenzie.com/en/newsroom/2018/07/chinese-lending-for-african-infrastructure
Gallagher, K. P. (2016). The China Triangle: Latin America's China Boom and the Fate of the Washington
Consensus. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Hudson Institute. (2016). The Index of Global Philanthropy and Remittances (2016). Washington DC: Hudson
Institute.
Hynes, W., & Scott, S. (2013). The Evolution of Ofcial Development Assistance: Achievements, Criticisms and a
Way Forward. Paris: OECD.
IMF. (2013). Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan Africa – Keeping the Pace. Washington DC: IMF.
Lin, J.Y., & Wang, Y. (2017). Development Beyond Aid: Utilizing Comparative Advantage in the Belt and Road
Initiative to Achieve Win-Win. Journal of Infrastructure, Policy and Development 1(2): 149–67.
Annex E: The quality of data on development nancing for PFM
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
97
Annex F: Mapping of PFM
assessment frameworks
The 2005 Paris Declaration on Aid Effectiveness
committed donors to harmonizing diagnostic
reviews and assessment frameworks for PFM to
lessen the burden on governments. The Public
Expenditure and Financial Accountability (PEFA)
program led the eld, but assessments have
subsequently proliferated, with the World Bank’s
Debt Management Performance Assessment
(DeMPA), the IMF’s Tax Administration
Diagnostic Assessment Tool (TADAT), and the
Public Investment Management Assessment tool
(PIMA) among the most well-known. A recent
review (PEFA Secretariat, 2018b) identied
45 distinct frameworks for assessing PFM
performance (Table 8), some of which cover the
entire government PFM system, while others were
developed exclusively for assessing subnational
governments, for evaluating specic elements of
the PFM system, or for development partners to
assess duciary risk.
These tools make a distinction between measures
for “benchmarking against good practices,
professional standards or thematic principles”
and “database tool(s) for comparison across
governments” (PEFA Secretariat, 2018b, p. 10).
The former seem to be standards, particularly
when they entail a non-narrative scoring system.
There is some uncertainty about terminology.
It seems that these should be referred to as
assessment tools rather than diagnostic tools,
since they assess against a framework rather
than identifying some underlying pathology. Yet
they are called diagnostic tools in much of the
literature. This report uses the terms “assessment
frameworks” and “assessment tools.”
Table 8: Mapping of PFM assessment tools
Custodian Tool Technical Coverage Instuonal Coverage
A. Broad PFM diagnoscs: diagnosc or analycal tools covering the whole of the PFM system
PEFA PEFAFrameworkforAssessingPublic
FinancialManagement
All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
IMF FiscalTransparencyEvaluaon(FTE) Transparency in all of PFM Naonal
OECD RecommendaonoftheCouncilon
BudgetaryGovernance(RCBG)
All of PFM Naonal
OECD InternaonalBudgetPracces&
ProceduresDatabase(IBPPD)
All of PFM Naonal
OECD SIGMAPrinciplesofPublic
Administraon(PPA)
All of PFM
Publicadministraon
broadly
Naonal
Internaonal
Budget
Partnership
OpenBudgetSurvey(OBS) Transparency in all of PFM Naonal
GlobalIniave
for Fiscal
Transparency
Principles on Fiscal Transparency
(PFT)
Transparency in all of PFM Naonal
WorldBank PublicExpenditureReview(PER) Expenditurepolicy
Expenditure
administraon
Naonal
Subnaonal
Sector
EuropeanUnion ECFINOperaonalAssessment(OA) All of PFM Naonal
98
Custodian Tool Technical Coverage Instuonal Coverage
WorldBank RapidAssessmentsandAconPlans
toImproveDeliveryinSubnaonal
Government(RAAP-ID)
All of PFM
Developmentoutcomes
andoutputs
Subnaonal
WorldBank MiGesonInstuonalCapacity
Diagnosc
All of PFM
Publicadministraon
broadly
Subnaonal
Councilof
Europe
BenchmarkingFiscal
Decentralisaon(BFD)
Fiscaldecentralizaon Subnaonal
B. Diagnosc tools that focus on individual PFM elements, instuons, or sub-systems
IMF TaxAdministraonDiagnosc
AssessmentTool(TADAT)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
WorldBank IntegratedAssessmentModelfor
TaxAdministraon(IAMTAX)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
OECD TaxAdministraonComparave
InformaonSeriesonOECDand
otherAdvancedandEmerging
Economies(TACIS)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
USAID CollecngTaxesDatabase(CTD) Revenueadministraon Naonal
EuropeanUnion FiscalBlueprints(EU-FB) Revenueadministraon Naonal
WorldBank HandbookforTaxSimplicaon
(HTS)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
IMF RevenueAdministraonFiscal
InformaonToolkit(RA-FIT)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
IMF RevenueAdministraonGap
AnalysisProgram(RA-GAP)
Revenueadministraon Naonal
Sector
WorldBank CustomsAssessmentTradeToolkit
(CATT)
Revenueadministraon
Tradefacilitaon
Naonal
EITI ExtracveIndustriesTransparency
Iniave(EITI)
Naonalresource
Revenueadministraon
Expendituremanagement
Naonal
Subnaonal
WorldBank StateOwnedEnterpriseCorporate
GovernanceandRiskToolkit(SoE
Toolkit)
Publiccorporaons Naonal
Sector
Singleinstuon
WorldBank DebtManagementPerformance
Assessment(DeMPA)
Debtmanagement Naonal
IMF PublicInvestmentManagement
Assessment(PIMA)
Investmentmanagement Naonal
WorldBank DiagnoscFrameworkforAssessing
PublicInvestmentManagement
(DF-PIM)
Investmentmanagement Naonal
Subnaonal
OECD MethodologyforAssessing
ProcurementSystems(MAPS)
Procurement Naonal
WorldBank PublicExpenditureTrackingSurveys
(PETS)
Expendituremanagement Naonal
Subnaonal
Sector
Annex F: Mapping of PFM assessment frameworks
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
99
Custodian Tool Technical Coverage Instuonal Coverage
WorldBank DiagnoscFrameworktoAssessthe
CapacityofaGovernmentFinancial
ManagementInformaonSystemas
aBudgetManagementTool(DF-
FMIS)
Managementinformaon
systems
Naonal
Internaonal
Records
Management
Trust
IntegrangRecordsManagementin
FMISDesign(IRM-FMIS)
Recordsmanagement Naonal
Subnaonal
Singleinstuon
WorldBank GapAnalysisFrameworkfor
ComparingPublicSectorAccounng
andAudingtoInternaonal
Standards(AA-GAP)
Accounng
Auding
Naonal
WorldBank ReportontheObservanceof
StandardsandCodesAccounng
andAuding(AA-ROSC)covering
accounngandauding,corporate
governance,andinsolvencyand
creditorrights
Publiccorporaons Naonal
Instuteof
InternalAuditors
InternalAuditCapabilityModel
(IA-CM)
Internalaudit Naonal
Singleinstuon
Internaonal
Organizaonof
SupremeAudit
Instuons
SupremeAuditInstuon
PerformanceMeasurement
Framework(SAI-PMF)
Externalaudit Naonal
African
Organisaonof
English-Speaking
SupremeAudit
Instuons
InstuonalCapacityBuilding
Framework(ICBF)
Externalaudit Naonal
Chartered
Instute
ofPublic
Finance and
Accountancy
FinancialManagementModel
(FMM)
All of PFM Singleinstuon
C. Tools used by development partners to make decisions on duciary risk
ADB AssessingandManagingGovernance
RisksinADBOperaons(AMGR)
All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
Sector
ADB FinancialManagementAssessment
(FMA)
All of PFM Singleinstuon
IADB ToolforDeterminingtheLevel
ofDevelopmentandUseofPFM
Systems(GUS)
All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
WorldBank AssessmentoftheUseofCountry
FinancialManagementSystemsin
Bank-Financed Investment Projects
Cashandexpenditure
management
Naonal
Subnaonal
100
Custodian Tool Technical Coverage Instuonal Coverage
EuropeanUnion BudgetSupportGuidelines(EU-BSG) All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
Sector
DFID FiduciaryRiskAssessment(FRA) All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
Federal Ministry
for Economic
Cooperaonand
Development,
Germany(BMZ)
BudgetSupportintheFrameworkof
Programme-OrientedJointFinancing
(BMZ-BSG)
All of PFM Naonal
Danish
Development
Cooperaon
(DANIDA)
GuidelinesforRiskManagement
(GRM)
All of PFM Naonal
USAID PFMRiskAssessmentFramework
(PFMRAF)
All of PFM Naonal
Subnaonal
Sector
Source:AdaptedfromPEFASecretariat(2018).
References
PEFA Secretariat. (2018). Stocktake of PFM Diagnostic Tools 2016. Washington DC: PEFA.
Annex F: Mapping of PFM assessment frameworks
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
101
Annex G: Relating the institutional
and economic perspectives on
PFM—a thought experiment
Among the most difcult and elusive questions
explored by the Working Group was the one that may
sound as if it should be the most straightforward:
how does PFM relate to public nance? Part
of the challenge is that PFM has established its
own standard objectives or “desirable budgetary
outcomes” (Campos & Pradhan, 1996; Schick,
1998; World Bank, 1998), which exist alongside,
and somewhat independently of, the classic public
nance policy objectives (Musgrave & Musgrave,
1989). This observation prompted the Working
Group to ask how the two sets of objectives might
relate to one another—whether incidentally or
intentionally.
It is striking that very few papers in the canon of
PFM literature since the mid-1990s even reference
Musgrave and Musgrave (1989). Notable
exceptions are Fozzard’s analysis of approaches to
resource allocation in budget policy (2001) and de
Renzio’s review dening budget institutions and
their desirable features (2009). To the extent that
it was a conscious choice over the past 25 years
to keep PFM and public nance policy separate
(Premchand, 1996), has that dichotomy become
too entrenched? Is it time for a reappraisal?
Conventional thinking on PFM since the late 1990s
has concentrated on identifying and strengthening
the elements of a PFM system that will contribute
to budget credibility and, thereafter, to the goals of
aggregate scal discipline, allocative efciency,
and operational efciency.
The total amount of money a government
spends should be closely aligned to what
is affordable over the medium term and, in
turn, with the annual budget; spending should
be appropriately allocated to match policy
priorities; and the spending should produce
intended results at least cost. (World Bank,
1998, p. 3)
These PFM objectives are often described as
“desirable budgetary outcomes” (Campos &
Pradhan, 1996), although the labelling as outcomes
is misleading. They are arguably more like the
means to an end than the end itself. Drawing on
literature about the administrative capacities of
the state, they might better be considered as a
set of institutional capabilities through which
the PFM system can support wider public policy
objectives (Krause et al., 2016; Lodge & Wegrich,
2014). What is certain is that these capabilities
(or standard PFM objectives, as described in this
report) have been highly inuential in producing
and reinforcing a strong set of conventions for how
the underpinning PFM system should look. This
leads to a further question: do the recommended
PFM capabilities enable governments to make
informed choices across all policy objectives,
or do they tilt the policy playing eld? In other
words, is there a policy bias inherent in the three
PFM capabilities?
Although the classic formulation of public nance
policy objectives—allocation, distribution, and
stabilization (Musgrave & Musgrave, 1989)—
predates the three PFM capabilities—aggregate
scal discipline, allocative efciency, and
operational efciency—it does not appear to have
driven their development and specication. The t
between the two sets is ambiguous and imperfect
(de Renzio, 2009).
Table 9 below conducts a thought experiment
about some of these relationships. It asks in which
ways the three PFM capabilities may be relevant
to the three public nance objectives and suggests
the relative strengths of those connections. What
emerges is a moderate-to-strong orientation of
standard PFM capabilities toward stabilization
and allocation, but only a weak-to-moderate
orientation toward distribution. (The analysis
assumes that operational efciency does not
have a strong implicit focus on the quality and
accessibility of service delivery.)
This focus on objectives compatible with
stabilization is not surprising given the prime
102
placement of aggregate scal discipline in the
trinity of PFM capabilities and its conventional
primacy in the hierarchy. The emergence of this
formulation in the late 1990s, at a time when
macroeconomic stabilization was high on the scal
policy agenda and when debt forgiveness under
the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries initiative was
prominent, makes it more evident why aggregate
scal discipline was emphasized (Premchand,
1996). To a secondary and subordinate extent,
expenditure allocation and efciency (allocative
and operational efciency) were on the agenda
because of concern about the use of scal space
following debt relief and in the presence of
program/budget support. Distributional concerns
such as inequality were less in focus for scal
policy and appear to receive less emphasis among
the PFM capabilities.
What is revealed most clearly is that the
PFM capabilities as laid out by Campos and
Pradhan (1996) appear to lack an emphasis on
distributional issues, whereas the public nance
functions described by Musgrave and Musgrave
(1989) appear not to focus on the choice of
instrument (or mode of delivery/intervention
by government). There seems to have been no
intention by the original proponents of the three
PFM capabilities to relate them to the three
objectives of public nance. This exercise lends
weight to the argument that some reappraisal and
debate may be needed. To borrow from Premchand
(1996), the “hierophanies” of PFM may need to
be reconsidered.
Annex G: Relating the institutional and economic perspectives on PFM
A thought experiment
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
103
Table 9: Capabilities of an effective PFM system and their relationship to

Public nance objecves (Musgrave & Musgrave, 1989)
Allocaon: “Theprovision
forsocialgoods,orthe
processbywhichtotal
resourceuseisdivided
betweenprivateand
socialgoodsandby
whichthemixofsocial
goodsischosen.This
provision may be termed
the allocaon funcon of
budgetpolicy”(p.6).
Distribuon: Adjustment
ofthedistribuonof
incomeandwealthto
ensureconformancewith
whatsocietyconsiders
a‘fair’or‘just’stateof
distribuon,herereferred
to as the distribuon
funcon”(p.6).
Stabilizaon: Theuse
ofbudgetpolicyasa
meansofmaintaining
highemployment,a
reasonabledegreeof
pricelevelstability,and
an appropriate rate of
economicgrowth,with
allowancesforeectson
trade and on the balance
ofpayments.Werefer
toalltheseobjecvesas
the stabilizaon funcon”
(p.6).
Instuonal
capabilies of
the PFM system
(Schick, 1998;
Campos &
Pradhan, 1996;
World Bank,
1998; PEFA
Secretariat,
2016)
Aggregate Fiscal
Discipline: “Budgettotals
shouldbetheresult
ofexplicit,enforced
decisions;theyshould
not merely accommodate
spendingdemands.These
totalsshouldbeset
beforeindividualspending
decisionsaremade,and
shouldbesustainableover
themedium-termand
beyond”(Schick,1998,
p.2).
Fiscal discipline is relevant
forallocaonbecauseit
determinesandxesthe
overalllevelsofpublic
revenueandexpenditure,
thuseecvelysengthe
levelofsocialgoodsinthe
economy.
Moderaterelaonship
Fiscal discipline is relevant
fordistribuonbecauseit
ensuresthattheagreed
levelsofpublicrevenue
andexpenditurearenot
breached,thusmakingit
feasiblefordistribuonal
incidence implied by the
budgettobeimplemented
inpracce.
Weakrelaonship
Fiscal discipline is relevant
forstabilizaonbecause
itensuresaggregate
controloverrevenueand
expenditurelevels,thus
keepingdebtanddecit
levelswithinagreedpolicy
thresholdsandsupporng
broader macroeconomic
management.
Strong relaonship
Allocave Eciency:
“Expendituresshouldbe
basedongovernment
prioriesandon
eecvenessofpublic
programs.Thebudget
systemshouldspur
reallocaonfromlesserto
higherprioriesandfrom
lesstomoreeecve
programs”(Schick,1998,
p.2).
Allocaveeciencyis
relevantforallocaon
becauseitdetermines
themixofsocialgoods,
basedonpolical
prioriesandprogram
eecveness.
Strongrelaonship
Allocaveeciencyis
relevantfordistribuon
becausedecisions
aboutthecomposion
ofpublicexpenditure
across sectors and
publicprogramswill
determinedirectly,or
aectindirectly,the
distribuonalincidence
ofthebudget.
Weakrelaonship
Allocaveeciencyis
relevantforstabilizaon
becausedecisionsabout
thespreadofpublic
expenditureacross
sectorsandprograms
mayaectthebalances
ofconsumpon/
investment,wage
bill/goods,imports/
exports,andsoon,
withknock-oneects
for macroeconomic
variables.
Moderaterelaonship
Operaonal Eciency:
Agenciesshould
producegoodsand
services at a cost that
achievesongoing
eciencygainsand(to
theextentappropriate)
iscompevewith
marketprices”(Schick,
1998,p.2)
Operaonaleciencyis
relevantforallocaon
becauseeciency
gains(orlosses)
andthussavings(or
overspending)within
or across years may
leadtochangesin
thecomposionof
spending,andthusthe
mixofsocialgoods.
Weakrelaonship
Operaonaleciencyis
relevantfordistribuon
becausethemixof
inputsinprovidingsocial
goodsmayaectpublic
sector employment and
thusincomes,andthe
degreeofexibilitymay
aectwagelevels.
Weakrelaonship
Operaonaleciencyis
relevantforstabilizaon
becauseunitcosts
andoutputeciency
may have an indirect
eectonprices,
andoutsourcingof
produconorprovision
to the private sector may
haveaneectonthe
economy.
Weakrelaonship
104
References
Campos, E., & Pradhan, S. (1996). Budgetary Institutions and Expenditure Outcomes (Policy Research Working
Paper No. 1646). Washington DC: World Bank.
de Renzio, P. (2009). Approach & Methodology for the Evaluation of Donor Support to Public Finance Management
(PFM) Reform in Developing Countries (Part A - Assessing Budget Institutions and Budget Reforms in
Developing Countries: Overview of Theoretical Approaches and Empirical Evidence). Oxford, UK: Fiscus
Public Finance Consultants, Ltd.
Fozzard, A. (2001). The Basic Budgeting Problem: Approaches to Resource Allocation in the Public Sector and
Their Implications for Pro-Poor Budgeting (Working Paper 147). London: ODI.
Krause, P., Hadley, S., Mustapha, S., & Welham, B. (2016). The Capabilities of Finance Ministries. London: ODI.
Lodge, M., & Wegrich, K. (2014). The Problem-Solving Capacity of the Modern State – Governance Challenges
and Administrative Capacities. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Musgrave, R. A., & Musgrave, P. B. (1989). Public Finance in Theory and Practice (Fifth Edition). San Francisco:
McGraw Hill.
PEFA Secretariat. (2016). PEFA: Framework for Assessing Public Financial Management. Washington DC: PEFA
Secretariat.
Retrieved from https://pefa.org/sites/default/les/PEFA%20Framework_English.pdf
Premchand, A. (1996). Issues and New Directions in Public Expenditure Management (Working Paper 96/123).
Washington DC: IMF.
Schick, A. (1998). A Contemporary Approach to Public Expenditure Management (35116). Washington DC: World
Bank Institute.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
Annex G: Relating the institutional and economic perspectives on PFM
A thought experiment
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
105
Annex H: A partial summary of
PFM research
In looking for cause and effect in moving between
“PFM interventions” and “results that matter,” it
is useful to review the causal evidence that: (i)
interventions as the unit of analysis have led to
improved conformity with basic conventions in
PFM; and (ii) they have led, along whatever route,
to improvements in nal results that matter. We
can also consider: (iii) whether the norms and
standards as the unit of analysis are themselves
associated with better results.
Given the high “causal density” (Woolcock, 2013,
p. 8) of the territory, with many factors in addition
to planned PFM development interventions
possibly leading to change, we can also look at
observed improvements and ask what caused
them. The questions here are: (iv) whether there is
a credible case that improvements at the national
level as the unit of analysis are attributable to
development interventions; (v) whether any
improved results are attributable to improvements
in conformity with the PFM conventions; and (vi)
whether improved conformity is itself attributable
to donor interventions (Figure 9).
Figure 9: Causal chains and attributions to be considered
Table 10 offers a partial summary of the literature reviewed for this report, with some representative research
summaries shown.
Table 10: A partial summary of key research
Element of the results chain Summary of evidence
(i)Didintervenonsleadto
improvedconformitywiththe
convenons?
Limited evidence
Thereissomebroadevidencethatbudgetsupportcanimprovethe
conformityofnancialmanagementandbudgetprocesseswithstandard
convenons(Orthetal.,2017,forexample).Amuchearlierstudyfound
thatimprovementsinPFM(thenmeasuredusingtheCountryPolicyand
InstuonalAssessment,orCPIA)hadtakenplaceinthemajorityof
countriesthatobtainedprojectsinthoseareas(IEG,2008).
Mostrecently,however,Fritzetal.(2017)foundthat,despiteeortsmadeto
strengthenPFMsystemsindevelopingcountriesovermanyyears,foralllow-
andmiddle-incomecountriescollecvely,boththePEFAindicatorsandthe
CPIA-13indicatorshowedonlysmallaggregateimprovementoverme.
TheobservaonmadebydeRenzioetal.(2010)remainsaconfounding
factor:thereisapossibilitythatdonorsbackwinnersormaybelosers,
suggesngthatstudyresultscouldincorporateunknowndegreesofbiasin
eitherdirecon.
106
Element of the results chain Summary of evidence
(ii)Didintervenonslead,along
whateverroute,toimprovements
innalscalresultsthatmaer?
Some evidence—parcularly concerning parcipaon and consultaon
DeLayetal.(2015)mappedintervenonstoresults,ndingthat
intervenonscouldimprovethepolicyrelevanceofresourceallocaon,
transparency,andscruny.Theyfoundthatreformsthatimproved
parcipaonandconsultaonhadthegreatestimpact.
(iii)Didconformitywiththe
convenonsleadtobeer
results?
Some evidence—parcularly concerning openness and transparency
Studiesthatfocusontheintroduconofspecicinstuonalarrangements
andpraccesshowthatthesehavesome,althoughratherlimited,impact
onresults(see,forexample,Goryakinetal.,2017;Mills,2018).Welhamet
al.(2017)ndthatbeerPFMisassociatedwithlowervariancesinoverall
budgetexecuonratesandthatabeerPFMsystemyieldslowerunder-ve
andinfantmortality,andhigherlifeexpectancyatbirth.
InreviewingcasestudiesoffragilestatesundergoingPFMreform,Hedger,
Krause,andTavakoli(2012)foundthatitwasnotclearifandwhenprogress
onPFMreformwouldcontributetothestate’sparcipaoninservice
delivery(WorldBank,2012).
Theimposionofscalrules(numericallimitsonbudgetaryaggregates),
drivenbyrecentexperiencesofscalconsolidaon(IMF,2010;Lassen,
2010;OECD,2010),hasatbestamarginalimpactonactualbehaviors.The
WorldBank(2012)wasmoreposivewithregardtotheimpactofMTEFson
scaldiscipline,butnotedthattheimpactofMTEFadoponontechnical
eciencyislesspronounced.
InanalysisbyMustaphaandLong(2019),countriesthatcrediblyenforced
penalesfornon-compliancecollectedmoretaxes.Knack,Biletska,and
Kacker(2017)foundthatstrongerprocurementproceduresledtofewer
kickbacks.deRenzioandWehner(2017)foundthatscalopennesshada
benecialimpact.
However,MustaphaandLong(2019)andFritz,Sweet,andVerhoeven(2014)
foundnostascallysignicantrelaonshipbetweenaPEFA-basedmeasure
ofoverallPFMqualityandthescalbalanceinbothnon-fragileandfragile
states,consistentwithAlesinaetal.(1999)andvonHagenandHarden
(1995).
(iv)Isthereacrediblecasethat
improvedresultsatthenaonal
orsectorlevelareaributableto
developmentintervenons?
No evidence either way
Thereisevidenceofgeneraldevelopmentprogress,butthisisnotevidently
aributabletoPFM(see,forexample,Radelet,2015).Thesameappliesto
majorsectorimprovements,asinthehealthsector(Morrison,2013).
(v)Areanyimprovements
inresultsaributableto
improvementsinconformitywith
convenons?
Lile evidence that improvements are aributable to PFM
Arecentreviewofhealthservicedeliveryimprovementsandthedegree
towhichtheseweredrivenbyPFMreforms,seeminglyassessedlargelyin
termsofconformitywithacceptedPFMconvenons,foundthatthereis
lileevidenceofacausalrelaonshipandtheresultsareoenconicng
(Welhametal.,2017).
Annex H: A partial summary of PFM research
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
107
Element of the results chain Summary of evidence
(vi)Isimprovedconformitywith
thePFMconvenonsaributable
todonorintervenons?
No evidence either way
Thisisdiculttoanswer,asthereislimitedevidenceofimprovedconformity
withPFMconvenons(see,forexample,Vani,2012).deRenzioetal.(2010)
foundamixedpictureinSub-SaharanAfrica,althoughtheGermanSociety
forInternaonalCooperaon(GIZ,2015)foundaslightlymoreposivetrend.
Ronsholt(2012)foundasomewhatposivepictureinexaminingchangesin
PEFAscoresovermein32countriesthathadbeenthesubjectofrepeat
PEFAassessments.
Lawson(2012)lookedatcountrieswherebudgetinstuonshadimproved,
boththosewith“highdonoreort”(BurkinaFaso,Tanzania,andZambia)
andthosewith“lowdonoreort”(Ethiopia,Ghana,andMali).Theywere
abletosaylileabouthowthedonorintervenonsmighthavecausedthe
instuonalimprovements,otherthanthroughrecognizedgeneralieslike
strongpolicalcommitment,reformdesignsandimplementaonmodels
thatweresuitedtothecontext,andstronggovernment-ledcoordinaon
arrangements.
Fritzetal.(2017)analyzedthecausesofcross-countryvariaonsinthe
qualityofPFMsystems,ndingthesetobeassociatedmostsignicantly
androbustlywithcountryincomepercapita(posively)andtheshareof
revenuesobtainedfromnaturalresources(negavely).Thesendingsare
consistentwithdeRenzioetal.(2010)concerningtheweakcorrelaon
betweenPFMsystemsandODAsupportforPFMreform.Totheextent
thatthereisanyimprovementinPEFAscores,deRenzioetal.(2010)
showedthatmostcountryvariaoninPFMqualityisduetoeconomicand
instuonalfactors.
Note:Theunitsofanalysisareitalicized.
References
Alesina, A., Hausmann, R., Hommes, R., & Stein, E. (1999). Budget Institutions and Fiscal Performance in Latin
America. Working Paper Series 394. Washington DC: IADB. Retrieved from http://www.iadb.org/OCE/
pdf/394.pdf
De Lay, S., Mills, L., Jadeja, K., & Lucas, B. (2015). Public Financial Management Evidence Mapping.
Birmingham, UK: GSDRC, University of Birmingham.
de Renzio, P., Andrews, M., & Mills, Z. (2010). Evaluation of Donor Support to Public Financial Management
(PFM) Reform in Developing Countries Analytical Study of Quantitative Cross-Country Evidence (Final
Report). Stockholm: Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency.
de Renzio, P., & Wehner, J. (2017). The Impacts of Fiscal Openness. The World Bank Research Observer(32),
185–210.
Fritz, V., Sweet, S., & Verhoeven, M. (2014). Strengthening Public Financial Management: Exploring Drivers and
Effects. Washington DC: World Bank.
Fritz, V., Verhoeven, M., & Avenia, A. (2017). Political Economy of Public Financial Management Reforms:
Experiences and Implications for Dialogue and Operational Engagement (121436). Washington DC:
World Bank Group. Retrieved from http://hdl.handle.net/10986/28887
GIZ. (2015). Good Financial Governance in Africa: Developments 2007–2014. Pretoria, South Africa: Deutsche
Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbei.
Goryakin, Y., Revill, P., Mirelman, A., Sweeney, R., Ochalek, J., & Suhrcke, M. (2017). Public Financial
Management and Health Service Delivery: A Literature Review. London: ODI.
Hedger, E., Krause, P., & Tavakoli, H.. (2012). Public Financial Management Reform in Fragile States. London:
ODI.
IMF. (2010). Strategies for Fiscal Consolidation in the Post-Crisis World. Washington DC: IMF.
108
IEG. (2008). Public Sector Reform: What Works and Why? Washington DC: World Bank.
Knack, S., Biletska, N., & Kacker, K. (2017). Deterring Kickbacks and Encouraging Entry in Public Procurement
Markets. Washington DC: World Bank.
Lassen, D. D. (2010). Fiscal Consolidations in Advanced Industrialized Democracies: Economics, Politics, and
Governance. Copenhagen: University of Copenhagen.
Lawson, A. (2012). Evaluation of Public Financial Management Reform in Burkina Faso, Ghana and Malawi
2001–2010: Final Synthesis Report. Oxford, UK: Fiscus Public Finance Consultants, Ltd.
Mills, L. (2018). Donor Support to Strengthen Public Financial Management in Partner Countries: Outcomes,
Experiences, and Ways Forward. Brighton, UK: Institute of Development Studies.
Morrison, J. S. (2013). Introduction. In J. S. Morrison (Ed.), Global Health Policy in the Second Obama Term.
Washington DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies.
Mustapha, S., & Long, C. (2019). PEFA, Public Financial Management, and Good Governance. Washington DC:
World Bank.
OECD. (2010). Fiscal Consolidation: Requirements, Timing, Instruments and Institutional Arrangements. Paris:
OECD.
Orth, M., Schmitt, J., Krisch, F., & Oltsch, S. (2017). What We Know About the Effectiveness of Budget Support:
Evaluation Synthesis. Bonn, Germany: German Institute for Development Evaluation.
Radelet, S. (2015). The Great Surge: The Ascent of the Developing World. New York: Simon and Schuster.
Ronsholt, F. E. (2012). Are Public Financial Management Systems Improving in Low and Middle Income
Countries? A Preliminary Analysis Based on Data from PEFA Assessments in 32 Countries. Washington
DC: PEFA.
Vani, S. (2012). Has Global PFM Improved in the Last Decade? Retrieved from https://blog-pfm.imf.org/
pfmblog/2012/09/has-global-pfm-improved-in-the-last-decade.html
von Hagen, J., & Harden, I. (1995). Budget Processes and Commitment to Fiscal Discipline. European Economic
Review, 39(3-4), 771–79.
Welham, B., Hart, T., Mustapha, S., & Hadley, S. (2017). Public Financial Management and Health Service
Delivery: Necessary, but Not Sufcient? London: ODI.
Woolcock, M. (2013). Using Case Studies to Explore the External Validity of ‘Complex’ Development Interventions.
Cambridge, MA: Harvard Kennedy School.
World Bank. (2012). Beyond the Annual Budget: Global Experience with Medium-Term Expenditure Frameworks.
Washington DC: World Bank.
Annex H: A partial summary of PFM research
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
109
Annex I: The elusive hope of
incorporating context
Problems in providing effective technical
assistance (or technical cooperation or capacity
building) are perplexingly persistent. Observations
made in 2001 are not vastly different from those
that might be made today:
In contrast to the historical process of
countries purchasing skills and know-how
from suppliers, the relationship now appears
very different...
Control: Demand was manufactured, not
self-generated. The capacity gaps came
to be perceived and funded by donor
country governments, not the recipients,
and control of the transfer arrangements
shifted accordingly. The recipient countries
owned neither the gaps nor the resources
put up to ll them. For as long as there has
been aid, there have been concerns about
country ownership.
Public sector bias: The reversal of control
was facilitated by the fact that aid was in
the public funding domain of the donors.
This had various consequences:
o Technical cooperation became the
preserve of bureaucratic minds and
processes in the donor countries, with
an often limited comprehension of the
character and context of the recipient
countries;
o Each donor bureaucracy devised its
own set of procedures and practices for
administering [technical cooperation],
resulting in a proliferation of
administrative paperwork;
o “Projectization” became a feature.
Technical cooperation was conceived
in time- and money-bound segments, a
conguration which best suited public
spending patterns.
Accountability: Aid had key stakeholders
in the donor countries, but beneciaries
elsewhere, setting up a potential tension
between two sets of objectives.
o The stakeholders had expectations
of how aid should “perform”, and
the criteria of success were often
commercial, political or in other ways
strategically signicant, rather than
developmental. (Morgan, 2001, as
cited in Browne, 2002, pp. 19–20)
These observations themselves showed that
the hope that the United Nations Development
Programme’s (UNDP) 1993 report on rethinking
technical cooperation (Berg, 1993) would
represent a “breakthrough in critical thinking” had
not been fullled (Table 11).
110
Table 11: Adaptive Management, Doing Development Differently, and Thinking
and Working Politically vs. Berg’s ideas from the early 1990s
Theme Andrews
(2012)
Teskey & Tyrrel
(2017)
Green
(2018)
Berg
(1993)
Bigger view Mustbeableto
developmulple
theoriesofchange
or theories of
acon(inparcular,
policalacon)for
every problem
Systemsthinking:
constantinteracon
and feedback
mechanisms
betweeneconomic,
social,andpolical
factors that can
variouslyenableand
inhibitchange
Focusonthewider
publicsector
environmentwithin
whichnewsystems
aremeanttowork
Learn as you go Problem-driven
learning
Purposivemuddling
Embedded
monitoringand
learning
Uncertaintyand
learningbydoing/
failing;natureofthe
problemnotknown
in advance
Local soluons Welcomelocal
hybridinstuonsif
theyfuncon
Mobilizelocalagents
intocommuniesof
change
Priorizetacit
knowledge,focuson
recruingstawith
policalknowledge
and“insider”
networksspecicto
the reform problem
at hand
Highnumbers
ofnaonalsta
inprogram
management
posions
Giveprioritytolocal
knowledge:“always
givetheworkback
togovernment—its
acoachingrole,not
usdoingthework”
(asquotedinGreen,
2018)
Priorizecultural
sensivity
over technical
competence
Greaterfocuson
training/capacity
buildingand
coachingandon
usinglocalsta
Flexibility in
allocaon of
resources and in
denion of objec
ves
Ability to make
acvityandbudget
modicaons;
adapngthe
programinrealme
Delegaonof
discreonover
budget,acvity
decisions,and
localnetworks/
relaonshipsto
programmanagers
Oppositeofdonors’
preference for
control,logframes,
riskminimizaon,
andpredictable,
tangibleresults
Delegaontolocal
sta
Move beyond
projectstoprograms
Emphasize
measurable outputs
Some things just
have to be done
Don’t be ashamed of
lling gaps if that is
what is needed
Annex I: The elusive hope of incorporating context
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
111
Theme Andrews
(2012)
Teskey & Tyrrel
(2017)
Green
(2018)
Berg
(1993)
Change the donor
architecture
Expose/createa
market for technical
assistance;charge
fullprice(even
ifgovernmentis
reimbursedby
donors in some
way)andunbundle
projects/programs
sothatgovernments
can pick and choose
whattheywant
Note: Italicizedphrasesarethosethataredierentfromornotfoundintheotherideas.
References
Andrews, M. (2012). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Baser, H., & Morgan., P. (2001). The Pooling of Technical Assistance. The Hague: Netherlands Ministry of Foreign
Affairs.
Berg, E. (1993). Rethinking Technical Cooperation: Reforms for Capacity Building in Africa. New York: UNDP
Regional Bureau for Africa and Development Alternatives Inc.
Browne, S. (Ed.) (2002). Developing Capacity through Technical Cooperation: Country Experiences. London and
Sterling, Virginia: UNDP and Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Green, D. (2018). Can ‘Doing Development Differently’ Only Succeed If Aid Donors Stay Away from It? .
Retrieved from http://oxfamblogs.org/fp2p/can-doing-development-differently-only-succeed-if-aid-donors-
stay-away-from-it/
Morgan, P. (2001). “Technical Assistance.” Background paper for the UNDP.
Teskey, G., & Tyrrel, L. (2017). Thinking and Working Politically in Large, Multi-Sector Facilities: Lessons to Date.
Canberra ACT, Australia: Abt Associates.
112
Annex J: Evolution in theories of
externally supported change in
the public sector
Historically, the eld of PFM advice has been
prone to advancing a series of relatively distinct
models for achieving change—each of which has
appeared to be clear and self-standing until the
next one arrived (Pretorius & Pretorius, 2009).
Table 12: Stylized theories of growth and of externally supported change in
public management
Decade Broad theories of economic
growth
Theories about public sector reform
Theories of externally supported
change
Underlying ideas
1960s Developmentpromoon
moreaboutcapitalows,less
aboutgovernmentpoliciesand
instuons.Emphasisoncapital
accumulaon,technological
adopon,andimportsubstuon
understateguidance.
Theoriesofpublicsectorinstuonal
reformwereimplicit,comprising
embeddedandunstatedassumpons
aboutllingcapacitygaps(knowledge,
ability,technicalexperse),parcularly
innewlyindependentcountries.
Gapllingincapital
and in capacity
1970s Capitalowsnotenough;turnto
macropolicies.
1980s Macronotenough;turntoa
morecomprehensivepackage,
includingscaldiscipline,
broadeningofthetaxbase,and
outwardorientaonthrough
freeingandenablingmarkets.
EmergenceoftheWashington
Consensus(Williamson,1989).
1
Theoriesofpublicsectormanagement
reformbegintoemergemoreexplicitly,
withagreaterfocusonincenvesinside
thepublicsectorthatcanbechanged
throughthetransferofbestpracces
(Levy,2010).Broaderincenvesofstate
actors,includingpolicians,excluded
fromdebate.
Reformcontentbegins
todominate(asin,this
reformisuniversally
therightthingtodo).
1990s Donorsseehighgrowthin
mediocrepolicyenvironments,
slowgrowthingoodpolicy
environments.Policiesnot
enough;turnto“instuons”
within“newgrowththeory”
(WorldBank,2005),thoughthe
noonofinstuonsisbroadly
andambiguouslyarculated.
Highnoonof“scalmachinery”
perspecve(Premchand,2000),with
itsemphasisonlinkingexpenditures,
atleastconceptually,withoutcomes
(WorldBank,1998).“Basicsrst”makes
anappearance(Schick,1998).
2000s Begintoadd“policalincenves
topursuedevelopment”into
themix.Demiseoftheoriginal
WashingtonConsensus;some
arguethatinadequateaenon
waspaidtooriginalinstuonal
concernsoftheWashington
Consensus(Singhetal.,2005),
othersthatthelistofinstuonal
Theoriesbecomemoreexplicitabout
matchingreformcontenttothecountry
instuonalcontext.Goodtdevelops
asaconcern(WorldBank,2000).
Contextualconsideraonsbroadened
toincludepolicalactors’incenvesto
implementreform.Increasingconcern
withshapingintervenonstomeet
policalrealies;nibblingawayat
Broadcountrycontexts
increasinglyseenas
primaryissue;reform
contenttobejudgedin
termsofitssuitability
forthecontext.
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
113
Decade Broad theories of economic
growth
Theories about public sector reform
Theories of externally supported
change
Underlying ideas
concerns needed to be
augmented(Rodrik,2006).
policalconstraintsatthemargin(as
intransparencyiniaves(UNDESA,
2001)).Theconceptofcontextalso
deepenedtoextendtosequencing
theories,suchasthePFMplaorm
approach(Brooke,2003)andthe
“StrengthenedApproach”(JointWorld
Bank/IMF/PEFAPublicExpenditure
WorkingGroup,2006).
2005
and
beyond
Connuingslowprogresssuggests
needforexperimentaon/
diversity.Recognionthatthere
aremulplepaths.“Another
mistake…inthe1990shasbeen
thetranslaonofgeneralpolicy
principlesintoauniquesetof
acons”(WorldBank,2005,
p.11).Overall,argumentfor
movingawayfromformulaic
policymakingtofocusonbinding
constraint(s).
Theoriesstarttoembraceactors’
subjecveunderstandingofthereform
processmoredirectly,sincetheproblem
thatistobesolvedinpublicsector
managementreformsisnotprimarily
“technical”but“adapve”(Heifetz,
1994).Noonsofchangespaceemerge
(Andrews,2013).
The process of
understandingthe
problemhasnow
becometherst-order
task.Contextremains
crical,andreform
contentiswhatever
can be contained
withinthespacethatis
foundtobeavailable.
2010
and
beyond
Socialmobilizaonisassociated
withchangedpolicalincenves
thatconstraingrowth,although
thereremainsuncertaintyabout
whichwaythecausalityruns
(Fukuyama,2010;Rodrik,2011).
Infrastructurebeginstotakea
largerplaceinpolicydiscussions.
Theoriesstarttosuggestthat
intervenonrequiresaner-grained
viewofthecontext(Kelsall,Booth,
Cammack&Golooba-Mutebi,2011).
Goodgovernancecansomemesbe
demanded,andchangingpolical
incenvestosupplygoodgovernance
maymeanimprovingcizencapacityto
demandgoodgovernance.
The process of
understandingthe
problem remains
preeminent,but
contextconsideraons
have become more
complex.Reform
contentistheresidual.
Source:ThistabledrawsonWorldBank(2005,2012).
References
Andrews, M. (2013). The Limits of Institutional Reform in Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Birdsall, N., de la Torre, A., & Valencia Caicedo, F. (2010). The Washington Consensus: Assessing a Damaged
Brand. Washington DC: Center for Global Development.
Brooke, P. (2003). Study of Measures Used to Address Weaknesses in Public Financial Management Systems in the
Context of Policy Based Support. Washington DC: PEFA.
Fukuyama, F. (2010). The Origins of Political Order. New York: Farrar, Straus & Giroux.
Heifetz, R. A. (1994). Leadership without Easy Answers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Joint World Bank/IMF/PEFA Public Expenditure Working Group. (2006). Supporting Better Country Public
Financial Management Systems: Towards a Strengthened Approach to Supporting PFM Reform
Harmonising Donor Practices for Effective Aid Delivery (Volume 2) (pp. 75–81). Paris: OECD.
Kelsall, T., Booth, D., Cammack, D., & Golooba-Mutebi, F. (2011). Developmental Patrimonialism? Questioning
the Orthodoxy on Political Governance and Economic Progress in Africa. London: ODI.
Levy, B. (2010). The Case for Principled Agnosticism. Journal of Democracy, 21(4), 27–34.
Premchand, A. (2000). Control of Public Money: The Fiscal Machinery in Developing Countries. Oxford: Oxford
University Press.
114
Pretorius, C., & Pretorius, N. (2009). Review of Public Financial Management Reform Literature. London: DFID.
Rodrik, D. (2006). Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Confusion? A Review of the World Bank’s
Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. Journal of Economic Literature,
XLIV(December 2006), 973–87.
Rodrik, D. (2011). The Poverty of Dictatorship. Project Syndicate. Retrieved from http://www.project-syndicate.
org/commentary/rodrik53/English
Schick, A. (1998). Why Most Developing Countries Should Not Try New Zealand's Reforms. World Bank Research
Observer (International), 13, 23-31.
Singh, A., Belaisch, A., Collyns, C., De Masi, P., Krieger, R., Meredith, G., & Rennhack, R. (2005). Stabilization
and Reform in Latin America: A Macroeconomic Perspective on the Experience since the Early 1990s.
Washington DC: IMF.
UNDESA. (2001). Globalization and New Challenges of Public Finance: Financial Management, Transparency and
Accountability Paper presented at the Meeting of the Group of Experts (28–30 November 2001), Rome.
Williamson, J. (1989). What Washington Means by Policy Reform. In J. Williamson (Ed.), Latin American
Readjustment: How Much Has Happened. Washington DC: Institute for International Economics.
World Bank. (1998). Public Expenditure Management Handbook. Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2000). Reforming Public Institutions and Strengthening Governance: A World Bank Strategy.
Washington DC: World Bank.
World Bank. (2005). Economic Growth in the 1990s: Learning from a Decade of Reform. Washington DC: World
Bank.
World Bank. (2012). The World Bank’s Approach to Public Sector Management 2011–2020: Better Results from
Public Sector Institutions. Washington DC: World Bank.
Annex J: Evolution in theories of externally supported change in the public sector
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
115
Annex K: Putting external
contestation of policy ideas into
practice
Institutionalized and disinterested contestation of
external policy ideas and advice will require effort,
as well as a change among and within development
assistance providers. Client governments could
draw more actively on multiple sources of advice
to inform their own independent positions and
choices. That would require structured contestation
among providers. At the same time, international
agencies and other providers of external advice
could introduce greater contestation of ideas as
part of their internal processes. They would need
to become more accustomed to their advice being
contested by client governments and compared to
alternative ideas and options.
Actions by client governments to
promote contestation
Several precedents can help in devising models
that support disinterested contestation of ideas
among multiple experts. They include the Elders
group of wise persons on international affairs,
the “Brain Trust” used by Franklin Roosevelt for
the rst and second New Deal in the 1930s, the
G20 Eminent Persons Group on Global Financial
Governance in 2017–18, the “Balcerowicz Plan”
and commission of experts on economic reforms
in Poland in 1989, the Independent Challenge
Group for the United Kingdom’s 2010 spending
review, the “Brain Trust” of advisers to Shinzo
Abe on economic policy from 2012 in Japan,
the “Wise Men” of economic forecasting in the
United Kingdom in the early 1990s, the “Iwakura
Mission” by Japan to the United States and Europe
in the 1870s, and the “Tswalu Dialogues” run by
the Brenthurst Foundation.
1
None of these examples is advocated as a template
for the contestation model proposed here—nor
are they without critique and criticism—but they
illustrate some possible variants. They all exhibit
a notable difference in character compared to
standard ofcial mechanisms such as the IMF’s
Article IV reviews and technical assistance
missions, the OECD DAC’s peer reviews, and
the European Commission’s Structural Reform
Support Service missions. In particular, they
have the inherent characteristics of a plurality
of perspectives beyond those provided by
ofcial agencies and the studied absence of any
ofcial positions or inuences. The plurality of
perspectives and views contrasts with the model
of individual high-level experts appointed as
independent external advisers to governments.
A shift is already underway from the consultant-
centric and supply-driven model of advice to one
in which multiple advisers present and debate
ideas and the government then decides which
approach to pursue. China has used this model
for external scal advice on its domestic reforms,
although the incentives at play for such a major
economic actor that does not require external
funding for advice are somewhat different than
those encountered in some other emerging and
lower-income economies. Emulating this type
of approach would involve a mechanism for
independent funding of external advisers and for
the government to set the agenda and control the
process, separate from the role and inuence of
development assistance or nance providers and
their downstream implementation consultants.
There are some relevant examples of the provision
of independent research, evidence, advice,
and ideas in lower-income settings to provide
alternative options for governments. One is the
role played by the International Growth Centre
on enterprise mapping and industrial policy in
Ethiopia. Other examples, which have been
deployed in Ethiopia and Rwanda, include third-
party funding for independent advice on tax policy
and external review of progress on Integrated
Financial Management Information Systems
reforms by a group of independent advisers. The
former was pre-funded, on-demand advice from
the United Kingdom’s Institute for Fiscal Studies,
and the latter was a mid-course review function
to examine and provide advice on challenges
around reform sustainability. In a similar mold,
116
the G7 CONNEX Initiative provides on-demand
independent advisory support to governments
of low-income countries in the negotiation of
complex commercial contracts in the extractive
sector. While institutionalized consideration and
contestation of alternative ideas is still novel,
these examples show that independent advice and
a “second opinion” approach are gaining ground
in lower-income countries.
There will inevitably be questions as to whether
structured contestation of ideas in a process led
by government is applicable and appropriate
in all country settings—especially in fragile
states. Ethiopia and Rwanda may well be on
track to following China’s approach of creating
mechanisms for institutionalized consideration
of alternative ideas and perspectives. There are
legitimate concerns, however, that some other
governments may lack capacity to orchestrate and
exploit this type of contestation and debate, or that
in practice the donors and IFIs that are funders
or nanciers of government will hold too much
passive inuence and thus crowd out real choice.
There is no clear indicator or proxy for the
conditions that are required in order for contestation
of ideas to be feasible and productive. It may be
that access to alternative and more diverse sources
of external nance, such as international capital
markets borrowing on competitive terms, signals
government capacity and downgrades donor
inuence (Haque et al., 2017). It may be that
strategic capability in government to articulate
priorities and make choices (as distinct from
technical capacity to run systems and processes)
is the important factor (Fritz et al., 2011; Krause,
2012). It may be that governments need to reach
the point where PFM shifts from a technocratic
concern of the nance ministry into a broader policy
concern for ministers of spending departments, so
that it is about government as a whole and not just
the nance ministry. Under these circumstances,
the salience of results from public spending could
override tradition in asserting the importance of
particular institutional arrangements for PFM.
The approach taken for the present report is
to avoid country categorization and instead to
consider how mechanisms can accommodate
risks as well as benets. It seems an unreasonably
constraining and short-term–and even conde-
scending–view to argue that some governments
cannot cope with options and choice, or that they
need not be fully informed about the spillovers
and trade-offs associated with particular choices.
Drawing on positive examples of putting external
contestation of policy ideas into practice, from
the full range of country settings, is an important
starting point. As Booth and Unsworth (2014)
point out, contestation is often part of the process
of working with complex coalitions during reform.
Actions within international
agencies to promote contestation
More debate and contestation of ideas is also
needed within international agencies to challenge
potential policy biases and reveal potential
spillovers and trade-offs. The difculty is to
devise mechanisms and provide models that
encourage group deliberation among people who
may disagree but who have a common interest
in developmental outcomes (World Bank, 2014,
p. 183). It is a well-established nding that
“contestatory modes of communication” are
helpful for “more fully exploring all sides of an
issue, for uncovering shared information, and for
reducing conrmatory bias” (Bächtiger & Gerber,
2014, p. 116) through a process of “collaboration
engineering” (Kolfschoten, de Vreede & Briggs,
2010). Within donor agencies there are frequent
rejoinders to strengthen the peer review process,
“institutionalizing teams that review plans in an
explicitly argumentative manner” or creating
teams that are institutionally distinct from the
proponents to create space for more candor and
critique (World Bank, 2014, p. 184). In addition,
exhausting available research evidence is
necessary, if far from sufcient (Ravallion, 2011).
Behavior change by the international agencies that
provide nancing and policy advice is difcult to
Annex K: Putting external contestation of policy ideas into practice
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
117
effect. The need for change and the obstacles to
change apply both to these agencies’ approaches
to external engagement with client countries and
to their internal ways of working in areas such
as peer review. The External Advisory Group to
a recent IMF review of capacity development
noted that: “…even when all parties agree that
change would, in principle, be a good thing, [it] is
difcult. Paradoxically perhaps, internally strong
and broadly effective organizations, like the Fund,
can suffer from status quo bias and inertia. Many
of the recommendations require that people in
the Fund do things differently than in the past
and … have a more concrete plan for how [to]
… overcome the powerful inertia of “business as
usual.” (IMF, 2018a, p. 5).
References
Abb, P., Köllner, P., & Maslow, S. (2016). The Role of External Policy Advice in China’s and Japan’s Economic
Policies since the Global Financial Crisis. Paper presented at the Interpretive Policy Analysis 11th
International Conference University of Hull, United Kingdom, 5 July 2016.
Alexander, D., & Lewis, J. M. (Eds.). (2015). Making Public Policy Decisions: Expertise, Skills and Experience.
Abingdon, UK: Routledge.
Bächtiger, A., & Gerber, M. (2014). ‘Gentlemanly Conversation’ or Vigorous Contestation?: An Exploratory
Analysis of Communication Modes in a Transnational Deliberative Poll. In K. Grönlund, A. Bächtiger, &
M. Setälä (Eds.), Deliberative Mini-Publics: Involving Citizens in the Democratic Process (pp. 115-134).
Colchester UK: ECPR Press, University of Essex.
Booth, D., & Unsworth, S. (2014). Politically Smart, Locally Led Development. London: ODI.
Fritz, V., Fialho Lopes, A. P., Hedger, E., Tavakoli, H., & Krause, P. (2011). Public Financial Management Reforms
in Post-Conict Countries: Synthesis Report. Washington DC: World Bank.
Haque, T., Bogoev, J., & Smith, G. (2017). Push and Pull : Emerging Risks in Frontier Economy Access to
International Capital Markets. Washington DC: Macroeconomics and Fiscal Management (MFM) Global
Practice, World Bank.
IMF. (2018). 2018 Review of the Fund’s Capacity Development Strategy—Report of the External Advisory Group.
Washington DC: IMF.
Kolfschoten, G.L., de Vreede, G.-J., & Briggs , R.O. (2010). Collaboration Engineering. In D. M. Kilgour & C.
Eden (Eds.), Handbook of Croup Decision and Negotiation, Advances in Group Decision and Negotiation
(pp. 339-358). London: Springer.
Krause, P. (2012). Public Financial Management Reforms in Fragile States: The Case of West Bank and Gaza.
London: ODI.
Ravallion, M. (2011). Development Impact Calls for Knowledgeable Development Practitioners. Retrieved from
http://blogs.worldbank.org/impactevaluations/development-impact-calls-for-knowledgeable-development-
practitioners
World Bank. (2014). World Development Report 2015: Mind, Society, and Behavior. Washington DC: World Bank.
118
Endnotes
Chapter 1
1.
The Australian Department for Foreign Affairs and Trade (DFAT), in its note urging development staff to address
PFM issues centrally, observes that:
Poor PFM can prevent governments from achieving their policy objectives, create uncertainty for the
private sector, and hamper growth and poverty reduction efforts. Unsustainable or volatile spending
may cause debt blowouts that limit a government’s capacity to pursue its objectives, and make it hard
for the private sector to plan and invest for the future. Inefcient resource allocation means funds
may not go to the top priority policies and most effective programs. Inefcient spending wastes
scarce public resources and can limit the quality and coverage of public services. Dysfunctional
PFM, including low levels of transparency and accountability, also raises the risk of corruption.
(DFAT, 2019, p. 3)
DFAT suggests that the relationship must hold true, but the problem in proving the connection more specically
lies in the challenges of evaluating impact (Keating, 2001). In a similar vein, the IMF in its recent review of
capacity building for public nancial management argues that:
Institutions are the foundation that supports sustainable economic development. They facilitate access
to economic opportunities, play a key role in the efcient allocation of resources, and in rewarding
human and capital investment, protect property rights and the rule of law, and help build resilience to
shocks and crises. (IMF, 2018a, p. 9)
2.
Experiences with pro-poor budgeting suggest that there is a dilemma about how starkly to reveal the trade-
offs entailed: too stark, and vested interests would ensure that technical warfare over models and assumptions
would engulf the budgeting process; too nuanced, and the impact would be lost. The question is how to make
distributive impacts a standard feature of policy making and reporting. A useful start could be to add impact
statements to the budget and government accounts, but the challenge is to nd a stronger and more universal
version of the arrangements attempted during the pro-poor budgeting era. Gender budgeting proposals of a
few years ago emphasized policy-related expenditure proposals (see, for example, Elson, 1999). More recent
proposals for climate change and mitigation approaches advise a more fundamental review of budgetary and
accounting procedures as well as options for modeling climate-related spending, suggesting that there are lessons
to be learned from recent experiences in examining pension and infrastructure liabilities (Gilmore & St. Clair, 2018).
3.
In September 2019, heads of state attended the High-Level Political Forum to review progress on the SDGs. They
were confronted with the facts that only 35 percent of low- and middle-income countries are “on track” to achieve
SDG targets related to meeting basic needs that are essential for a decent quality of life (such as proper nutrition,
access to sanitation, and gender equality of opportunity) and that only 18 percent of fragile states are “on track”
(Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, 2018; IMF, 2018b; Kharas, McArthur & Rasmussen, 2018; Samman et al.,
2018). The meeting concluded that the world is not on track to achieve the target of bringing the population living
in extreme poverty under 3 percent of the world population by 2030 (United Nations, 2019). Financing of the
SDGs is, unsurprisingly, also off track. For emerging market economies, the average additional annual spending
required in 2030 to reach key SDGs stands at 4 percentage points of gross domestic product (GDP), compared
to 15 percentage points of GDP for the average low-income developing country (Gaspar, Amaglobeli, Garcia-
Escribano, Prady & Soto, 2019).
4.
At times of rapid growth, new challenges can be addressed through distribution, rather than redistribution, of
the benets of growth. At times of slower growth, this strategy is ineffective, since resources have to be taken
away from existing commitments and constituencies—a much higher political bar to clear. This paper comes at
a time of weakening in global growth. Trade tensions are high, developing economies are experiencing nancial
stress, and risks to global growth have increased. Emerging markets (most prominently Argentina, Brazil, China,
Mexico, South Africa, and Turkey) and developing economies face some of the greatest risks. The slowdown is
most marked in Africa and East Asia. While per-capita GDP continues to increase, the growth slowdown signals a
major challenge for those who manage public nances as they seek to respond to expectations for public services,
particularly from the more politically connected middle classes. Deterioration in services will place poor people
under particular pressure. Austerity measures imposed by countries to offset budget decits could prove to be
politically difcult to maintain and may lead to destabilizing protests, as in the case of the July 2018 disruptions
in Haiti (Coats, 2019; World Bank, 2019a).
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
119
5.
The trend toward refocusing on ends more than institutional means, and on policy objectives more than on the
stability of the scal machinery, is a reminder that PFM can have only a partial inuence alongside broader
economic, social, and political factors (Weingast, Shepsle & Johnsen, 1981).
6.
As the IMF acknowledges in a review of its own program design and conditionality between 2011 and 2017,
“there was limited focus on the quality of social spending, and on social protection and inequality, more generally”
(IMF, 2019, p. 24).
Chapter 2
1.
Any allusion to history in public management risks the accusation that it has failed to acknowledge key historical
developments. To avoid this criticism, tribute should be paid here to the writings of Max Weber who noted that a
modern bureaucracy acts, in principle, as a lasting, impartial, rule-abiding, and non-partisan executor of laws and
regulations, which are devised by the political leadership (Weber, 1978). Weber observed (but did not prescribe)
that these traits were more likely to be found in hierarchical organizational structures staffed by career ofcials
operating within stable and comprehensive sets of rules. Pritchett and Woolcock (2004) remind us that, while
Weber made these observations in Western Europe, Western Europe did not invent rational bureaucracy, as shown
by the long history of bureaucracy in China and India).
2.
This thinking opened up contentious debates following some initial enthusiasm for exibility and internal trading
arrangements branded as “new public management” (Hood, 1991), quickly giving way to skepticism about the
feasibility of such dramatic moves (Manning, 2001; Schick, 1998b).
3.
Drawing on evidence from Brazil, Peru, Indonesia, Madagascar, and Cambodia, Ringold (2012) points out that
PFM and other institutional weaknesses act as a block on social accountability.
For social accountability mechanisms to inuence service delivery, changes are needed in the behavior
and the content of the work of frontline service providers. If the incentive framework under which
providers operate isolates or protects them…social accountability mechanisms, such as scorecards
or hotlines, are unlikely to work well. Social accountability is not just a ‘demand-side’ concern. The
mechanisms…cannot be considered separately from the broader incentive framework under which
providers operate. (Ringold, 2012, pp. 94–95)
There is similar empirical evidence from Kenya (Sheely, 2014).
4.
Detailed survey evidence and robust research in the Philippines have shown that vote buying is robustly correlated
with lower levels of services that are within local control, that are pro-poor, and that are not targeted at particular
groups. Thus, for example, expenditures on local health services, which the rich tend not to use, diminish in the
presence of vote-buying (Khemani, 2013). Non-programmatic parties do not have a broad membership base that
is able to discipline party leaders. Again, research has shown that, under these circumstances, party leaders are
less likely to focus public expenditures on:
the more proximate determinants of development: education and the accumulation of human capital;
infrastructure; security, including the protection of property and contract rights; public health; or the
proper regulation of market failures, ranging from the environmental to the nancial. (Keefer, 2013,
p. 2)
5.
The starkest example of PFM constraints to effective service delivery are cash budgeting and cash-rationing
practices. There are, of course, factors outside of PFM that are also essential for effective service delivery—not
least oversight and accountability, managerial attitudes, and staff engagement with the tasks at hand.
6.
See IMF World Economic Outlook (WEO) denitions and classications, in particular (IMF, 2018c).
120
7.
Fiduciary risk tools include:
ADB AssessingandManagingGovernanceRisksinADBOperaons
ADB FinancialManagementAssessment
IADB ToolforDeterminingtheLevelofDevelopmentandUseofPFMSystems
WorldBank Assessment of the Use of Country Financial Management Systems in Bank
Financed investment Projects
EU BudgetSupportGuidelines
DFID FiduciaryRiskAssessment
BMZ Strategy181:BudgetSupportintheFrameworkofProgramme-OrientedJoint
Financing
Danida GuidelinesforRiskManagement
USAID PublicFinancialManagementRiskAssessmentFramework
Source: Developed from PEFA Secretariat (2018b).
Donors often accompany these assessments with a parallel, but strictly unrelated, concern about fungibility:
did the aid provided for one donor-approved purpose free up government nancing for a different purpose that
the donor might consider unproductive? Donors are frequently subject to intense scrutiny from politicians who
are skeptical about the use of taxpayers’ money to nance activities in other countries and prompt to condemn
spending on activities they do not support. When donors doubt the capacity of the government to reallocate
nancing in line with development priorities, they often turn to distinctive project instruments that seek to limit
fungibility as well as to provide duciary assurance.
8.
The reform areas captured in Figure 3 are dened as follows:
Forecasting and strategic budgeting Macro and revenue forecasting, program-based budgeting, zero-based
budgeting, medium-term expenditure frameworks, participatory budgeting, program impact studies, gender
budgeting
PFM legislation – Introduce budget circulars, committees for budget debates, create budget ofce in parliament
to help assess proposals, increased legislative oversight, scal decentralization, enact scal rules, budget
classication systems, debt management frameworks, budget cycle changes, public-private partnership legal
framework
Treasury Single Accounts – Consolidate governments’ cash resources to ensure that revenue is stored in one
place. In countries with fragmented government banking arrangements, the establishment of a Treasury Single
Account should receive priority in the PFM reform agenda to increase overall traceability and accountability of
funds
Core Financial Management Information Systems (FMIS) infrastructure – Refers to an ecosystem of information
technology (IT) infrastructure that supports the daily functions of public entities by tracking and summarizing
nancial events and data. These systems automate core activities such as budget preparation (e.g. compiling
of expenditure plans from different departments), nancial reports generation, and improved ease of access to
nancial data. Reforms include capex on hardware and software, digitization of (including historical) data, and
capacity building within the civil service to use the IT systems prociently
Expenditure side reforms More efcient and transparent practices (independence of procurement bureaus,
promote transparent bidding through electronic and competitive procurement, standardized forms), effectiveness
of service delivery, improved subsidy targeting mechanisms such as identication means (e.g. Aadhaar in India),
payroll reforms including human resource management systems
Revenue side reforms – Digital tax collection, increasing taxpayer convenience, remittances management,
increased taxpayer buy-in, effectiveness of revenue collection agencies, promote and strengthen independence
of collection body
Accounting and reportingAdopt accrual accounting standards, professionalizing the accounting function,
standardizing charts of accounts, applying international standards to classication of fund stocks and ows
Internal audit and control Programs to support Ofce of the Auditor-General, capacity building (e.g. analysis
of public expenditure reports), strengthen internal controls and monitoring standards, procure and use of software
to improve productivity, increased ability to prosecute, internal control and compliance
External audit and monitoring Publish civilian budgets, maintain updated scal portals to increase transparency,
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
121
PEFA assessments, public reports to raise awareness on budget matters, public investment information systems,
funding non-governmental organizations (NGOs) in audit and monitoring
(AlphaBeta, 2018)
9.
The sector classication of OECD DAC Purpose Codes is dened as follows: “The sector of destination of a
contribution should be selected by answering the question ‘which specic area of the recipient’s economic or social
structure is the transfer intended to foster’” (see https://www.oecd.org/dac/stats/purposecodessectorclassication.
htm). In this classication of development nance statistics, “public nance management” (purpose code 15111)
is treated as separate from “domestic revenue mobilisation” (purpose code 15114), “local government nance”
(purpose code 15128), and “public procurement” (purpose code 15125). AlphaBeta (2018) follows the OECD
DAC classication and includes only data under the 15111 “public nance management” purpose code in its
analysis of external nance.
10.
“Men [sic] of the sociological tribe rarely visit the lands of the physicists and have little idea of what they do over
there. If the sociologists were to step into the building occupied by the English department, they would encounter
the cold stares if not the slingshots of the hostile natives” (Becher & Trowler, 2001, p. 45).
“Despite decades of talk about ‘interdisciplinary courses’…there is a strong belief that such talk is just talk. Those
thought to be sober mostly presume that real scholarship means getting on with the advancement of knowledge
organized exclusively by disciplines and sub-disciplines. It does not seem to matter that some knowledge may
not contribute to an intelligible whole…” (Orr, 1993, p. 10).
11.
“…academic discipline can be seen as a form of specic and rigorous scientic training that will turn out
practitioners who have been ‘disciplined by their discipline’ for their own good. In addition, ‘discipline’ also
means policing certain behaviours or ways of thinking. Individuals who have deviated from their ‘discipline’ can
be brought back in line or excluded” (Krishnan, 2009, p. 8).
12.
The existence of disciplines within development can have a downside. Levy (2014) identies the somewhat
shameful conicts within the World Bank when considering governance reforms between, on the one hand,
“governance advisers who saw the strengthening of ‘country systems’ within the public sector as key to
effectiveness” and, on the other, “protagonists who gave priority to more bottom-up, community-based
approaches” and champions of “vertical global programs” which, the governance advisers felt, undercut country
ownership and “added new difculties to the challenge of strengthening country systems” (p. 5). In a zero-sum
competition for prominence and project nance, the “wins” for one side can mean that the knowledge of the other
side is lost.
13.
“…in ve of the eight cases (Afghanistan, DR Congo, Liberia, Sierra Leone, and West Bank and Gaza), the
appointees formerly worked for international nancial institutions for a period of time. From a government’s
perspective, such appointments serve a dual purpose. A minister with an international background may be
expected to serve as a champion of PFM reforms while at the same time being expected to liaise effectively
with the international community and to ensure external assistance ows. In Afghanistan and the DR Congo, in
particular, such appointments were made during early post-conict years when relations with the international
(aid) community needed to be established” (Fritz et al., 2011, p. 6).
14.
Sixty-eight self-identied public nancial management specialists working in development completed an online
survey.
15.
Commonly recognized as:
1. Budget preparation and approval phase with strategic decisions made that translate policy objectives into
nancing in the context of revenue forecasts with budgets then prepared, generally for submission to the
legislature
2. Budget execution phase in which governments implement, or not, the actions necessary and agreed for
nancing to achieve their policy objectives, with revenues collected and resources distributed to spending
agencies with cash liquidity and debt managed. Internal control and audit procedures ensure compliance with
rules and manage risks, the maintenance of records, and reports on the execution of the budget, all with the
aim of monitoring and controlling compliance with budget appropriations.
3. The external audit and policy review phase completes the cycle. Supreme audit institutions are responsible
for public external scrutiny of the government’s annual nancial statements or equivalent, examining whether
government nancial activities were carried out in compliance with the original budget law, and respecting
all other rules and procedures. Sometimes, although perhaps more often aspired to than achieved, this phase
includes an ex-post analysis of impact of government policy programs.
122
16.
“Many European countries have started changing their accounting systems by adopting a set of standards largely
inspired by International Public Sector Accounting Standards (IPSAS) issued by the IPSAS Board (IPSASB). As
the IPSASB has no legitimate power, the adoption of the IPSAS in local and central governments is completely
voluntary…. In the European Union (EU), since 2012 Eurostat is working on a project for the harmonization of
[public sector accounting] of member states and decided for the development of a European PSA standards set,
which will consider IPSAS as a reference” (Rossi, Caperchione, Cohen & Brusca, 2019, p. 237).
17.
These are set by the Committee of Sponsoring Organizations of the Treadway Commission.
18.
Professional PFM bodies and their standards and basis for membership.
Professional body Explicit standards Implicit norms Membership
CharteredInstuteofPublic
FinanceandAccountancy
Individual
CommieeofSponsoring
Organizaonsofthe
TreadwayCommission
Standards for internal
controls
ExtracveIndustries
TransparencyIniave
EITI Standard Naonallevel
IMF Fiscal Transparency Code
IMF RevenueAdministraonGap
AnalysisProgram
InstuteofInternalAuditors InternaonalProfessional
PraccesFramework
Individual
InternaonalAccounng
StandardsBoardwithin
InternaonalFederaonof
Accountants
InternaonalPublicSector
AccounngStandards
Individual
InternaonalOrganizaonof
SupremeAuditInstuons
InternaonalStandardsof
SupremeAuditInstuons
Agencylevel
WorldBank CustomsAssessmentTrade
Toolkit
WorldBank ReportonObservanceOf
StandardsandCodes–
AccounngandAuding
Source: Developed from PEFA Secretariat (2018b).
The depth of knowledge that these bodies are drawing on is reected to some degree by the size of their
membership. For example, the Institute of Internal Auditors, a professional body based in the United States,
serves 185,000 internal auditors in nearly 190 countries (Allen, 2018).
19.
Since their separation from political scientists a century or so ago, public administration and management specialists
start with the problem that they do not draw on a distinct academic discipline (Guy, 2003; Raadschelders 2018).
The study of public administration has multiple theories and many generalizations, but these have not coalesced
into a distinctive body of knowledge recognized for its ability to predict the future course of organizational or
societal behavior. Any broad progress is limited by the confounding effect of context and deeply embedded
cultural traditions within the public sector, which prove difcult to pin down.
For example, the Germanic tradition can be stated as an ideal type, but the structure and functioning of German
and Dutch governments are very different. Historical occupation by France is generally seen as the test for what
constitutes a Napoleonic country, but Italy and the Netherlands are hardly alike.
The challenge of tradition is compounded by the cultural dominance of the Anglosphere; American and British
textbooks are translated into Chinese, Korean, and Spanish, but the reverse is not (as) true. Blurring the conceptual
boundaries even further, the language used to distinguish key components of the public sector can confuse. The
position of civil servant in the Netherlands and China is legally dened; in the United Kingdom it is sociologically
dened as someone who works in Whitehall or for the government; and in France and Germany the distinction
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
123
between higher- (fonctionnaire, Beamte) and lower- (employee, Angestellte) level civil servants is both legally
and sociologically dened (Raadschelders 2018).
Although never stellar, the prestige of the public administration eld has waned in the last half century,
overshadowed by economics and widely seen as craft-based rather than knowledge-based work, drawing on
practical skills required for work in the public sector (Kettl, 2000; Vitale, 2013).
20.
While Evans and Rauch (1999) show a causal link between the quality of public administration and economic
growth, for example, examination of growth accelerations such as those in China after the late 1970s and in
South Korea from the early 1960s do not reveal any signicant public sector management reforms that preceded
them (Hausmann, Pritchett & Rodrik, 2005). Current evidence points to those that protect the returns on private
investment, in particular property rights and the rule of law, but beyond that, it is not clear which institutions are
causally related to economic development and, in fact, the direction of causation might be the reverse, with richer
societies demanding better governance structures (Booth, 2015).
21.
For example, “a TADAT assessment report will not…include recommendations for specic reforms….Rather,
the report will—in highlighting weaknesses of administration—provide the basis for discussions about reform
goals, implementation strategies, and prioritization and sequencing of interventions” (TADAT Secretariat, 2015,
p. 6).
22.
For example, “the PEFA methodology draws on PFM international standards and good practices as identied by
experienced practitioners and academics…” (PEFA Secretariat, 2018a, p. 3).
23.
The use of convention compliance as the approach for understanding PFM arrangements has arguably been
strengthened by two other factors. First, as credit rating agencies have broadened their scope and increased their
activities, they have found indicators such as those elaborated by the PEFA program useful in justifying their
claim that many countries need oversight because of their institutional weaknesses (Paudyn, 2014). Second, in
contexts of low staff capacity, the existence of a set of standards facilitates the efcient development of staff
competencies (Kirkpatrick & Kirkpatrick, 2009).
There is an evolving “ecology” of diagnostic tools as well. For example, as China provided support to the belief
that economic development required large investments in infrastructure, public investment management became
more prominent in the tools. As domestic resource mobilization became recognized as a key constraint, revenue
gap analysis emerged.
24.
“The inuence of the ‘good governance’ debate saw a convergence in thinking about tax administration in much
the same way as the previous period led to convergence in tax policy advice. Today, most developing countries
have not only rationalised their tax systems by replacing trade taxes by indirect taxes but have also invested
in a standard set of reforms with a view to modernising their administrations. This is best illustrated in the
establishment of semi-autonomous revenue authorities (SARAs), which can be dened as tax administrations
which operate with a degree of autonomy from their nance ministries. First established in Jamaica, the model has
spread to Latin America, Africa, Asia and recently Greece. In line with [New Institutional Economics] thinking,
ring-fencing the administration from political interference supposedly signals a credible commitment to a less
discretionary tax collection process, which in turn should boost compliance… However, the effect of SARAs is
subject to debate.
The creation of these new authorities coincided and sometimes facilitated the modernisation of specic tax
administration processes and brought them into line with best practices from NPM. Reforms focused on increasing
efciency by reducing collection costs and increasing compliance by approaching taxpayers as customers. …(E)
xamples of some of the key reforms:
Increasing the reliance on information technology.
Introducing unique taxpayer identication numbers.
Re-organising the collection system from one organised around different taxes, to one organised around
individual taxpayers.
Segmenting taxpayers by, for example, establishing large taxpayer ofces.
Separating back- and front-ofce functions to reduce the scope for bribery.
Creating ‘one-stop shops’.
Simplifying procedures” (Dom & Miller, 2018, p. 21).
25.
Campos and Pradhan (1996) contrasted the emphasis on contracting and output specication in New Zealand
with the emphasis on delegation within hard constraints in Australia in the 1990s.
26.
A term coined by Richard Batley, Emeritus Professor of Development Administration, University of Birmingham.
27.
The difculties of obtaining data about the internal workings of the public sector have been noted in the social
124
science research literature for many years (Jakobsen & Jensen, 2014). New budgetary procedures can be proposed
and agreed, but implementing a new accounting framework requires changing the hard-to-observe behavior of
thousands of public servants, many of whom can continue old habits while claiming to have introduced the policy
wholeheartedly.
28.
“In technical situations, where the authority has the expertise to dene and solve the problem…let the experts
do their job. Adaptive situations, however, tend to demand a more participative mode of operating to shift
responsibility to the primary stakeholders” (Heifetz, 1994, p.121). As Booth (2014) rather memorably puts it
in reference to some complex institutional reforms in the Philippines, “this was a guerrilla operation, not a war
of xed positions” (p. ix). Similar arguments have been made for OECD countries (Pollitt & Bouckaert, 2011).
Melchor (2008) and the OECD (2005) both observe and welcome the prevalence of incremental adaptation in
reform. We can see this in practice when nance ministries “try out” a new approach to budgeting, accounting,
procurement, and the like for a limited number of agencies for a limited period of time to test how things work
(Kristensen, 2019). This is consistent with the observed experiences of PFM reform in East Asia (So, Woolcock,
April, Hughes & Smithers, 2018).
Incrementalist and adaptive approaches are often attributed to the changing thinking in economics (Rodrik,
2008), but they have a history in public administration: the need for reform processes that allow iteration and
adaptation has long been identied (Brinkerhoff & Crosby, 2002; Brinkerhoff & Ingle, 1989); Evans (2004) has
warned against institutional “monocropping” when “deliberation” is more appropriate; and Ellerman (2005) set
out a radical critique of donor agencies’ tendencies to know best.
Much of the academic and research discussion of this comes under the broad heading of “design thinking”
(Clarke & Craft, 2019; Howlett, 2009).
29.
Ear (2009) provides a fascinating case study of donors confronted by bureaucratic politics and rivalries that they
did not recognize or understand.
30.
Andrews, McNaught, and Samji (2018) provide a good example of how PEFA scores were used as the basis for
dialogue with nancial management staff across government in Mozambique.
31.
Williamson’s observations were that there was a consensus among IFIs in Washington concerning the need
for: (1) scal discipline; (2) a redirection of public expenditure; (3) tax reform; (4) nancial liberalization; (5)
adoption of a single, competitive exchange rate; (6) trade liberalization; (7) elimination of barriers to foreign
direct investment; (8) privatization of state-owned enterprises; (9) deregulation of market entry and competition;
and (10) protection of property rights (Williamson, 1989).
32.
There is arguably some difference in the formulations of the second objective (allocative efciency) among Schick
(1998a) (“expenditures should be based on government priorities and on effectiveness of public programs. The
budget system should spur reallocation from lesser to higher priorities and from less to more effective programs”);
World Bank (1998) (“allocation of resources in accordance with strategic priorities”); and PEFA Secretariat
(2016) (“strategic allocation of resources involves planning and executing the budget in line with government
priorities aimed at achieving policy objectives”). Whereas Schick includes an emphasis on performance in the
second objective (that is, with regard to the effectiveness of public programs), the World Bank appears to address
that dimension as part of the third objective on operational efciency (“efcient and effective use of resources
in the implementation of strategic priorities”). The PEFA Secretariat takes a more ambiguous middle path. In
practice, these differences of emphasis across objectives and their formulation are not signicant when all three
objectives are treated interdependently. Nonetheless, they do reveal the important interpretive inuence of the
leading experts and organizations in the international PFM eld.
33.
Cangiano et al. (2013a) argue that:
It is important to dispel a potential misunderstanding of the meaning of the rst PFM key objective, maintaining a
sustainable scal position. This objective should not be seen as, and certainly does not imply, a bias toward scal
tightening. It is a way to achieve legitimate macroeconomic objectives, most notably inclusive and balanced
growth, in an orderly fashion without prejudging the state of public nances, which may, in turn, have negative
repercussions on macroeconomic stability and growth. (p. 2)
Chapter 3
1.
The literature points clearly to the important effects of country-specic factors on PFM reform outcomes (Evans,
2008; Peterson, 2010; Pretorius & Pretorius, 2009, p. x; Scott, 2011). The constraints posed by human capital
limitations and economic endowments on PFM reform prospects have been explored in both case-specic and
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
125
cross-national analysis (Fritz, Sweet & Verhoeven, 2014; Haque, Knight & Jayasuriya 2012). Context is about
both the intricate pressures that cause actors to adapt, perhaps even distort, budget practices to everyday realities
(Stevens, 2004) and the features of the broader political system in which stakeholders engaged in PFM reforms
are embedded. The overwhelming importance of country context in determining which reform approaches and
measures will be successful, and in which ways, is a statement about both the primacy of country factors and the
limits of external ones, most notably donor inuence.
2.
Two kinds of reactions can be distinguished. One entails the manipulation of the measures or criteria that are
selected. In this case, the operations remain the same but the representation of these operations is deliberately
skewed by selecting indicators that give preferred results. This results in a loss of data quality. The alternative is
to alter the output itself. This usually results in a loss of output quality. A combination of both is also possible:
Source: Van Dooren (2006), cited in Van Dooren et al. (2006).
There is an extensive literature on the challenge of gaming, exemplied by Charles Goodhart’s “Law,” which he
developed following his analysis of the consequences of the Government of the United Kingdom relying solely
on money supply targets in the 1970s: “Any observed regularity will tend to collapse once pressure is placed on
it for control purposes” (Goodhart, 1975). Risks and remedies are set out in Courty and Marschke (2004) and Van
Dooren et al. (2006).
3.
Knowledge transfer and the genuine replication of practices across settings are hard to achieve in an objective
sense, irrespective of the possibility of an underlying incentive to game the assessments. Evidence from the
corporate sector about “internal stickiness” is relevant and instructive here: “the major barriers to internal
knowledge transfer are shown to be knowledge-related factors such as the recipient's lack of absorptive capacity,
causal ambiguity, and an arduous relationship between the source and the recipient” (Szulanski, 1996, p. 28).
Especially for those dimensions of the assessment frameworks that focus on “functional” reforms more than
merely “formal” ones (Andrews, 2012), the likelihood of gaming may be further diminished.
4.
De Lay et al. (2015) provide a more comprehensive treatment of the research difculties.
5.
The sequencing debate is based around the premise that some basic disciplines (typically around managing PFM
inputs and human resource management) should be entrenched prior to more advanced public sector management
reforms, including arrangements for measuring and managing outputs and/or performance. This case was most
prominently articulated in Schick (1998b) and the associated mantra of “look before you leapfrog.” This was
followed by the World Bank’s Public Expenditure Management Handbook (World Bank, 1998), which stressed
the importance of getting the basics right rst:
Control inputs before seeking to control outputs
Account for cash before moving to accrual accounting
Operate a reliable budget for inputs before moving to budgeting for results
Make a comprehensive budget and reliable accounting system before trying an integrated nancial
management system
Get a proper budgeting and accounting function before strengthening the auditing function
Do reliable nancial auditing before trying performance auditing.
This logic was operationalized most clearly in PFM in the platform approach proposed by Brooke (2003) and
in the “hurdle approach” to PFM reform in Thailand (World Bank, 2002), where competence in a set of internal
ministry processes were prerequisites for enhanced autonomy, including budget planning, output costing,
procurement management, budget and funds control, nancial and performance reporting, asset management,
and internal audit. A recent and comprehensive summary of assumptions concerning what comes rst is set out
in Diamond (2012).
6.
See https://pefa.org/news/enhanced-standards-pefa-reports-launch-new-pefa-check-criteria.
126
7.
A 2018 survey of leaders of development agencies found “a fragmented development ecosystem and an ever-
expanding cast of players… During this upheaval, development leaders are innovating, harnessing technology
in exciting ways, using data to drive decision-making, and empowering partners on the front lines. They are
painfully aware that not all of their organizations are likely to accomplish their goals or continue to exist in their
current form. Overall, the survey results paint a picture of a global development sector rife with experimentation
and transition” (Ingram & Lord, 2019, p. 1). “Among issues seen as neglected or insufciently resourced, climate
change tops the list, followed by youth, state fragility, and governance” (Ingram & Lord, 2019, pp. 5–6).
8.
See, for illustration, Eno, Glentworth, Hedger & White (2018).
9.
Current and past examples include the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, the Tony Blair Institute for Global
Change (formerly the Africa Governance Initiative), the CABRI network of African budget ofcials, the
“Building State Capability” program at Harvard Kennedy School, the “Budget Strengthening Initiative” and
Fellowship Scheme at the Overseas Development Institute, the International Growth Centre, the African Centre
for Economic Transformation, the Harvard Institute for International Development, the Duke University Center
for International Development, the National Institute of Public Finance and Policy in India, the Development
Policy Centre at Australian National University, the Scott Fellows scheme at the Center for Global Development,
the United Kingdom’s Institute for Fiscal Studies, the Korea Institute of Public Finance, the Center for
International Development at Korea Development Institute, the Center for Excellence in Finance, the Oxford
Policy Fellowship, and the Blavatnik School of Government at Oxford University.
10.
“…unless developing countries are offered genuine choice about which aid agencies they want to work with,
the effectiveness of aid in reducing poverty will decline and the rhetoric about recipient country ownership will
remain empty” (de Renzio & Rogerson, 2005, p. 1). Moreover, Browne (2012) sees open choice and competition
among different development models as key to major transformations in each of the last three centuries (Peter the
Great’s modernization of Russia in the early 18th century, Japan’s opening up to economic and institutional advice
from outside in the mid-19th century, and China’s request for modernization through capital investment and skill
development from the League of Nations in the early 20th century). In these cases, the countries “decided on their
best course of action and purchased overseas the skills that they lacked… The client country paid and the jobs got
done the way the client wanted” (Browne, 2012, pp. 23–24).
11.
The emergence of competition is generally accompanied by attempts to suppress it. “It is peculiar that an
abundance of suppliers is criticised in the ‘aid market’, when economics underline the virtue of competition
almost everywhere. However in the world of aid, the presence of many donors does not imply competition among
them, but more often superposition of costs and administrative procedures” (Santiso & Frot, 2010). Interagency
competition in development assistance is evidently present but publicly decried.
12.
“Financing a separate facility with like-minded donors to compete directly with current players offering PFM
advice and implementation support. One example of such a facility is the Global Fund for Women, where BMGF
is a key contributor. The Global Fund for Women has group of core sponsors that appear to have little or no
control over the decision making of the fund which is governed by a board of directors represented by personnel
from diverse geographies and backgrounds. The board is supported by an extensive list of global experts that
provide due diligence, outreach, and analysis which guide the fund’s activities” (AlphaBeta, 2018, p. 5).
13.
This is the “expertise-and-policy-advice tail that wags the development dog” (Browne, 2012, p. 163).
14.
Countries “value exibility and the use of country systems, speed of delivery, and alignment to their national
strategies. When considering the nancial terms for debt resources, a minimum grant element of 35% of the
nominal value of the loan (the IMF benchmark for low-income countries) would be the prevailing criterion for
the Ministries of Finance in Ghana and Senegal when seeking project-type nance. However, both countries
chose to pay signicantly more for Eurobond issues and syndicated regional loans offering much larger volume
and exibility. Timor-Leste sets the return on its offshore reserves as a ceiling on borrowing rates” (ODI/OECD,
2014, p. 8).
15.
“Viewed as a quasi-market, the aid industry is now maturing.… [T]he consumers – in this case, the aid recipients
are beginning to have a modest inuence on the pricing and product behavior of suppliers (aid donors). An
interesting trend to track in the coming years will be whether concessional aid suppliers begin to compete with
one another on the basis of brand and other non-price attributes” (O’Keefe, 2007, p. 10).
16.
“For example, a market for technical assistance similar to ‘eBay’ would enable developing countries to set out
their requirements, enabling a bigger variety of providers to bid according to the terms of reference. Service
providers would [be] able to earn (or lose) [their] reputation based on feedback from previous clients provided
through the online system. Reports and analysis from such technical assistance would all be shared online”
(Barder, 2009, p. 35).
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
127
17.
Seemingly, Barder (2009) has choice in mind when he argues for what he terms a “collaborative market.” “Aid
funders could make more use of market incentives to encourage innovation and efcient delivery of services,
and to close down ineffective or unnecessary programmes and organisations.…Networks hold the promise of
increasing and improving information and…reducing transactions costs, to help to close the feedback loop
between beneciaries and funders, and providing a platform for collaboration. Using markets and networks
together more effectively may permit decentralized and uncoordinated decision-making to produce collectively
benecial outcomes in transparent and regulated markets” (Barder, 2009, p. 37).
18.
It is currently popular in development circles to argue that the linear logic of logframes and so on, with their
implication of an inevitable chain of cause and effect, from input to output to outcome (DFID, 2009; Team
Technologies, 2005), should be replaced or at least supplemented by a “theory of change” that allows for
uncertainty and unpredictable contingencies, reecting a disorderly “real world” picture, with the possibility that
different paths might lead to change (Valters, 2015).
In reality, there is immense confusion about the meaning of theories of change, partly because they originate
from two perspectives: an evaluation perspective, seeking to dene how inputs are linked to outcomes, and a
“social action” perspective, emphasizing participation and continuing reection as action proceeds (Vogel, 2012).
The result is that a theory of change can be anything between, on the one hand, a rebranded logframe and, on
the other hand, an action perspective that suggests that there cannot be certainty about the consequences of any
intervention and that small steps, informed by careful observation and participation, are the only way forward.
While the Working Group is agnostic about whether current thinking offers practical ways forward, it endorses
two ideas implicit in current debates about theories of change. First, it considers that the linear logic of logframes
is more appropriate for building bridges than for reforming institutions. Local context matters and the responses
of the actors cannot be fully predicted in advance (Porter, Allen & Thompson, 1991). Whatever the terminology,
the design of an intervention must allow for contingency and must answer the question of why the relevant
actors will make the changes assumed within a reform program. The design of programs must be “autonomy-
respecting” (Ellerman, 2005). Simply asserting that a different way of doing things will be better is a weak
lever, and compulsion in development cooperation has proved to be both infeasible and ineffective. Second,
approaches to reforming institutional arrangements must always rest on a “theory” of some sort about why
facilitating particular managerial or institutional changes will lead eventually to the desired improvement through
the results chain. “All development activities – projects, programs, policy reform, technical assistance, training
workshops, capacity building, research and evaluation – therefore operate on the basis of a theory of change, even
if this theory is only implicit and never articulated” (Pritchett, Woolcock & Andrews, 2010, p. 1). The challenge is
to make that theory more explicit so that it produces predictions that are capable of being falsied. Observations,
insights, and lessons may then feed back into rened theory.
19.
Lawson notes that many of the institutional reform case histories he analyzed raised examples of policy space
constraints:
“In Malawi, Procurement reforms and Internal Audit reforms were both premised on the use of ‘best practise’
models in which responsibilities would be decentralised. This would have required new skills to be developed
and embedded in virtually all government institutions. These models were fundamentally inappropriate to
a context of signicant shortages of trained staff within the civil service, combined with the persistence of
hierarchical modes of working, limited accountability and a culture of frequent disregard of rules. Simpler
reform models were needed, less demanding of organisational and human resource capacities.
The BPEMS reform in Ghana was based on a technology-driven model, which gave insufcient attention to
change management issues, and to the assessment of capacity constraints and training needs. It was also based
on an ambitious ‘big bang reform’ approach rather than a more gradual, ‘incrementalist’ approach. Again this
was a ‘best practise’ model, which was inappropriate to the context.
The MTEF reform in Ghana presented a different type of policy space constraint, in that the consultants
leading its introduction selected and promoted an idiosyncratic model, which was never likely to achieve
the desired outcomes of an MTEF. The reform design was idiosyncratic rstly, in placing emphasis on the
‘bottom-up’ elements of an MTEF (programme-based budgeting, detailed costing of plans, integration of aid-
nanced projects) and barely mentioning the upstream elements (macro-scal framework, strategic policy
and expenditure review processes) that are conventionally seen as the initial priorities in establishing a robust
MTEF process. Secondly, it adopted an activity-based budgeting approach to the development of multi-year
budgets, which generated voluminous, highly detailed documents, which made it very difcult to discern the
strategies and priorities underlying MDA budgets, thus effectively defeating the purpose of the exercise.
128
In Burkina Faso, the problem was essentially a failure to sequence work on the medium term expenditure
framework and programme budgets in an adequate manner. It involved the attempted introduction of programme
budgets before there was an aggregate medium term scal framework in place, when many sector policy and
strategy frameworks were unclear and when the processes for tracking performance during budget execution at
the programme level were yet to be designed.” (Lawson, 2012, p. 61)
20.
Robust peer review must involve teams that are institutionally distinct from the proponents, in order to create
space for more candor and critique (World Bank, 2014, p. 184).
21.
The problem of “domain narcissism” (a phrase coined by Professor Richard Marcy, Assistant Professor of
Organizational Behavior at the University of Victoria School of Public Administration)—in which one discipline
seeks dominance over others, employing a narrowing of perception and rejection of incompatible information
from other disciplines, and with an associated degree of emotionalism—is well-recognized (see, for example,
Alexander & Lewis, 2015).
Chapter 4
1.
The same is true of all “upstream” public sector management arrangements since “sustained improvements in
education, health, and other sectors downstream often depend on institutional reforms upstream, at the center of
government” (World Bank, 2012b, p. 18).
2.
The connection between service delivery and outcome is about quality. In a seminal review of output measurement
for the United Kingdom government, Tony Atkinson and others pointed out that the quality of an output, or
service, is really a measure of “the attributable incremental contribution of the service to the outcome” (Atkinson
et al., 2005, p. 42).
3.
As a group of leading PFM experts noted in their evidence submission to the last PEFA review process:
The PEFA framework was not designed to identify why indicators were scoring poorly and can only
suggest crudely which broad areas…might require attention and more specic diagnostics. Yet in
developing countries, PEFA assessments are sometimes used formulaically to develop a detailed
PFM reform plan or to justify a wide range of highly ambitious interventions. One example is the
2009 Maldives’ Action Plan for PFM Reforms, though there are many others such as Sierra Leone’s
PFM Reform Strategy and Tajikistan’s PFM reform programme. (Krause et al., 2014, p. 1).
4.
For example, “the next generation of indicators will have to minimize the use of normative-based best practices
and help devise better metrics, with shifted emphasis on contextual functionality and actual implementation
rather than on announcement effect so that substance can prevail over form” (Cangiano, 2017, p. 380).
5.
Although stronger or more intentional variants could be considered, there would be risks around mandate,
legitimacy, and incentives. For example, the National Institute for Health Care and Excellence in the United
Kingdom (https://www.nice.org.uk/).
6.
“While the rationalist approach elevates information and analysis as the basis for budgetary decision making,
seeking to achieve an optimal allocation of resources, the incrementalists demonstrate that political considerations,
institutional role play and bounded rationality provide a more accurate depiction of budgetary behaviour”
(Fozzard, 2001, p. 33). In addition, Fozzard (2001) writes:
The nature of the budget process also promotes incremental decision-making. Allocation decisions
tend to be made sequentially – between Ministries of Finance and individual spending agencies
and then by reviews of agency proposals within collegiate bodies such as Cabinet and in legislative
committees rather than by assessing trade-offs between alternative claimants. Furthermore,
budgeting is repetitive, with the same allocation issues being addressed in successive budgeting
exercises. In this way, participants arrive at a tacit agreement regarding each claimants ‘fair
share’, constituting a ‘convergence of expectation on roughly how much an agency is to receive in
comparison to others’ (Wildavsky, 1992: 87). Once the fair share is established, bargaining about
allocational decisions is restricted to the distribution of additional resources rather than redistribution
the budget base. This reduces the risk of cutthroat competition between rival claimants for resources
and means that allocations do not have to be revised every year. Instead, the process is ‘premised on
agreement on the size, scope and distribution of expenditure. Conict was conned to the margins, a
little more here, a little less there’ (Wildavsky, 1992: 73). Without this stability, incrementalists argue,
the budgeting process would descend into chaos” (p. 30).
7.
The argument here is that, with baselines, the starting point for producing next year’s budget is this years
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
129
budget plus built-in increases such (for example, an increased number of pensioners or ination adjustments
for benets). Policy changes are dened as cutbacks when they reduce spending below the baseline, even when
spending is above current levels. MTEFs extend the baseline to the medium term, incorporating only agreed
spending increases and, only rarely, spending decreases, as the basis for future budgets (Schick, 2013).
8.
The Building PFM Capabilities program was developed by CABRI, in collaboration with the Building State
Capability Program at Harvard’s Center for International Development. The program uses the Problem Driven
Iterative Adaptation approach to support PFM reform and was successfully completed by seven African countries
in 2017 (Ababou, 2019).
9.
There are diverse examples of how the design of the PFM system is overtly adjusted to reect the policy goals
and decisions of the government:
The government may decide on a scal rule to contain public spending within a xed ceiling of GDP, or to limit
the annual growth of expenditure. The PFM challenge would then be to design the appropriate rule and develop
a monitoring mechanism to ensure that it is enforced.
The government may announce a new policy to achieve greater gender equality. The budget system may then
need to be redesigned to include a gender budget statement, appropriate provisions in the annual budget circular,
a framework for conducting gender impact assessments and gender audits, an extension of the performance
budgeting system, and so on (IMF, 2017b).
The government may decide that it wants to give a degree of preference to national contractors and suppliers in
the procurement process. To implement this policy, the law may need to be changed and adjustments made to
tendering procedures.
The government may decide to boost tax collection by establishing a large taxpayer unit, providing special
incentives for large taxpayers to comply with the statute, and streamlining collection procedures.
All of these examples may also require changes to the primary PFM law or other PFM-related laws or regulations,
as well as changes to business processes, manuals, and instructions for nancial managers; changes to IT systems;
and so on (Allen, 2019).
There are also “covert” connections, such as the discontinuation of Public Service Agreements in the United
Kingdom to facilitate austerity measures. The introduction of Public Service Agreements for public expenditure
was devised as a means to justify and defend spending increases in the Spending Review. They were discontinued
as a way to make spending cuts easier under austerity. The recent emphasis in the United Kingdom on the
management of scal risks and of the government balance sheet (asset management) was an institutional response
to a policy emphasis on (continuing) cuts and austerity, as well as a response to large outsourcing failures and
greater post-crisis surveillance (Hughes, 2019).
10.
“When evaluations are commissioned ex ante with a specic objective to identify budgetary savings across
government, however, they require some specic characteristics in order to full this role. These kinds of
evaluations, or spending reviews, can be used to reduce the decit and/or to make scal space for higher priority
programmes either through restructuring or cutting activities. While spending reviews can also look at programme
effectiveness, i.e. how to improve programme performance and design, their distinguishing feature is the focus
on identifying and extracting savings through the budget process” (Lau, 2011).
11.
The four dimensions proposed are political, social, organizational, and process (Catalano & Erbacci, 2018).
12.
Experiences with pro-poor budgeting suggest that there is a dilemma about how starkly to reveal the trade-offs
entailed: too stark and vested interests would ensure that technical warfare over models and assumptions would
engulf the budgeting process, too nuanced and the impact would be lost. The question is how to make distributive
impacts a standard feature of policy making and reporting. A gentle start would be to add impact statements to
the budget and government accounts—but the challenge is to nd a stronger and more universal version of the
arrangements attempted during the pro-poor budgeting era.
13.
Elson (1999) gives a avor of this in her suggestions concerning the adjustments needed for effective gender
budgeting:
1. Gender-aware policy appraisal
This analytical approach involves scrutinizing the policies of different portfolios and programs by
paying attention to the implicit and explicit gender issues involved. It questions the assumption that
policies are ‘gender neutral’ in their effects and asks instead: In what ways are the policies and their
associated resource allocations likely to reduce or increase gender inequalities?
130
2. Gender-disaggregated beneciary assessments
This research technique is used to ask actual or potential beneciaries the extent to which government
policies and programs match their priorities.
3. Gender-disaggregated public expenditure incidence analysis. This research technique compares
public expenditure for a given program, usually with data from household surveys, to reveal
distribution of expenditure between women and men, girls and boys.
4. Gender-disaggregated tax incidence analysis
This research technique examines both direct and indirect taxes in order to calculate how much
taxation is paid by different individuals or households.
5. Gender-disaggregated analysis of the impact of the budget on time-use.
This looks at the relationship between the national budget and the way time is used in households.
This ensures that the time spent by women in unpaid work is accounted for in policy analysis.
6. Gender-aware medium-term economic policy framework
This attempts to incorporate gender into the economic models on which medium-term economic
frameworks are based.
7. Gender-aware budget statement
This process may utilize any of the above tools. It requires a high degree of commitment and
coordination throughout the public sector as ministries or departments undertake an assessment of
the gender impact of line budgets. Elson (1999), cited in O'Hagan & Klatzer (2018, p. 24).
14.
“Reforms in public expenditure management and in donor practice, combined in the pursuit of poverty reduction
strategies, offer some grounds for hope of increased effectiveness in pro-poor social sector expenditure
programmes. However, the implementation of reforms will be a slow process and resource reallocation to favour
high impact programmes is likely to meet institutional and stakeholder resistance” (Roberts, 2003, p. xi).
15.
A comparable initiative in climate budgeting, led by the UNDP and the World Bank in the late 2000s and early
2010s, revealed similar challenges and was also inconclusive on the evidence (World Bank, 2014a, 2014b).
16.
There has been renewed interest in OECD countries—especially following the global nancial crisis—in evidence
and lessons on spending reviews to identify savings and reallocate them to higher priorities, as well as in the
development of a framework to capture dimensions that support “cutback management” in public expenditure
(Catalano & Erbacci, 2018; Lau, 2011; Robinson, 2013).
17.
“The notion that scal consolidations can be expansionary (i.e., raise output and employment), championed,
among others, in the academic world by Harvard economist Alberto Alesina or in the policy world by former
European Central Bank President Jean-Claude Trichet, has been seriously debunked. Instead, the short-run costs
must be balanced against the potential longer-term benets that consolidation can confer” (Ostry et al., 2019,
p. 78). Clements, de Mooij, Gupta & Keen (2015) “do not suggest that countries should not undertake scal
consolidation…however…the benets of scal adjustments should be weighed against their likely distributional
impact… History shows that scal plans succeed when they permit “some exibility while credibly preserving
the medium term consolidation objectives”… (and) “equity considerations suggest that a larger share of the
adjustment burden could be borne by the rich, which could be achieved through revenue measures targeted at the
higher income segments of the population” (Clements et al., 2015, p. 156). “…the overall effect of redistribution
is pro-growth, with the possible exception of extremely large redistributions. There is no negative direct effect,
and the resulting lower inequality seems to be associated with longer growth spells” (Ostry et al., 2019, p. 105).
18.
Fiscal biases play out very differently in advanced and low-income economies. In advanced economies, when
the economy stagnates, built-in or discretionary scal policies enable an increase in decit spending. When low-
income countries stagnate (often because of a decline in the market price of critical commodities), the opposite
occurs: the government is compelled to tighten its belt, thereby aggravating economic misery. The double
standard that allows rich countries to use decit nancing and compels poor countries to austerity is not itself due
to PFM, but it is critical that PFM institutions be mobilized to counter this bias.
19.
See also European Union surveillance reports for a review of scal structural reforms (European Commission,
2019). There is much discussion of the tension between the approach adopted by the troika in Greece and the
softer advocacy of IFIs. Ostry et al. (2019) write: “…on scal policy, the IMF’s then-chief economist Olivier
Blanchard said ‘what is needed in many advanced economies is a credible medium-term scal consolidation, not
a scal noose today’ (IMF, 2010). In October 2013, the IMF’s managing director Christine Lagarde applauded
the decision by the U.S. Congress to raise the country’s debt ceiling. On the pace of U.S. scal consolidation,
Lagarde advised: ‘we say slow down because the point is not to contract the economy by slashing spending
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
131
brutally now as recovery is picking up’ (Howell, 2013). For the euro area, the IMF advocated that ‘those with
scal space should use it to support investment’” (p. 108).
20.
“Austerity could easily have spared the poor, if the political will had existed to do so. Resources were available to
the Treasury at the last budget that could have transformed the situation of millions of people living in poverty…”
(Alston, 2018, pp. 22–23).
21.
The primary argument for increased public spending on infrastructure is that it will promote growth through the
impact of improved transport, water supply and sanitation, and information and communications technology on
the productivity of private enterprise and the rate of return on capital, particularly when stocks of infrastructure
assets are starting from a relatively low base. Reliable power grids and well-maintained roads reduce the need for
the private sector to spend on maintenance of its own stock of physical capital and have a direct impact on health
and education outcomes. This previously theoretical claim is now backed up by some growing empirical evidence
and has been given momentum by China’s “Belt and Road” infrastructure, trade, and investment initiative, which
has attracted the participation of more than 70 countries since its launch in 2013. The initiative has benetted
from China’s framing of its engagement with the developing world as one of “non-interference” in implied
contrast to the ideologically driven traditional donor model promoting democratic governance and human rights
(Abiad, Furceri & Topalova, 2015; Agénor & Moreno-Dodson, 2006; Lin & Wang, 2017).
22.
Questions about inclusion and broader well-being are now being more actively researched and debated in the
context of economic prosperity. The case is growing for “inclusive prosperity,” under which “the ‘inclusive’
modier demands both that we consider the whole distribution of outcomes, not simply the average, and that we
consider prosperity broadly, including non-pecuniary sources of well-being, from health to climate change to
political rights” (Naidu et al., 2019, p. 1).
23.
Musgrave and Musgrave (1989) write:
As noted before, budget policy involves a number of distinct objectives, but these overlap in practice,
thereby complicating an efcient policy design, i.e., a design which does justice to its diverse goals.
Suppose rst that the public wishes an increased supply of public services. Increased taxes are needed
to pay for these, which leads in turn, to the question of how they should be distributed. Depending on
what taxes are used, taxation may well change the distribution of income that remains available for
private use. Hence some voters may favor (reject) the proposed change in public services because they
like (dislike) the associated change in distribution rather than because they like (or dislike) the public
service. Ideally, the two issues would be separated: Society would provide for what is considered a
fair state of distribution and then adjust the nancing of public services in line with the benets which
taxpayers derive there-from. Because this two-step procedure is difcult to accomplish, decisions on
the provision of public services tend to be mixed with and distorted by distributional considerations.
Similar reasoning also applies in the reverse direction, when the supply of public services and hence
taxes are reduced.
Next suppose that society wishes to shift distribution in the direction of greater (lesser) equality. Such
a shift may be accomplished by using progressive (regressive) taxes to nance transfers to lower
(higher) incomes. But it may also be done by increasing (reducing) the supply of public services of
particular value to low (high) income groups. This, however, interferes with the pattern of public
services which consumers want to obtain at a given distribution of income. Once more, one policy
objective may be implemented such that it interferes with another.
Finally, consider the role of scal policy in stabilization. Suppose that a more (less) expansionary
policy is needed. This may be accomplished by raising (lowering) outlays on public services or by
reducing (raising) the level of taxation. In the former case the allocation objective of scal policy is
interfered with, whereas in the latter it is not. However, in the latter case there is the further question
of how changes in the level of taxation are to be implemented. For stabilization measure to be neutral
regarding both allocation and distribution goals, proportional changes in the level of taxes might offer
the appropriate solution.
As we will see in the course of this study, there are many exceptions which call for qualication of
the simple rules just given. Nevertheless, it is important to keep in mind that there are three distinct
policy objectives and policy should try to minimize conicts among them. (pp. 13–14).
24.
Concerning the taxation-accountability relationship, Welham et al. (2013) argue that some of the political science
accounts of how states came about in different historical contexts have been picked up by the development policy
community and employed to understand contemporary states. They note that the most prominent account suggests
132
that today’s states grew out of a mutually reinforcing process of tending to the needs of warfare, which led to
ever-rising taxes, which in turn eventually prompted increasing accountability to taxpayers (Tilly, 1992). The
observation that the nature of a state’s tax regime strongly inuences governance goes back to Schumpeter (1918),
cited in Welham et al. (2013), and has been applied by Moore (2013) to contemporary developing countries. The
detrimental effect of not needing to tax one’s own citizens, mainly in the context of natural resource wealth, has
been much debated in economics and political science (Collier & Hoefer, 2005; Ross, 1999).
25.
PFM and scal policy responses to the decit-nanced spending hikes in the aftermath of the Arab Spring risk
adding to the very social pressures that led to the unrest in the “Arab Countries in Transition” (Finger & Gressani,
2014).
26.
An open government in the OECD is understood as one under which businesses, civil society organizations,
and citizens have increased their power to know what has been decided (transparency), to obtain their legitimate
service entitlement (accessibility), and to be heard (consultation and participation) (OECD, 2005). Freedom of
information legislation has been important in establishing rights of access to information and has been adopted
by over 90 percent of OECD member countries. More “active” forms of openness involve publishing government
datasets (Open Data), giving citizens greater opportunities to engage in the design and delivery of services (Open
Services), and engaging with citizens in policy making (European Commission, 2013).
The G8 Open Data Charter implicitly recognizes that making government data more open has an impact
on improved governance and public sector innovation only if those data can be reused by others outside of
government to interact with the public sector and create new services. For this to happen, datasets need to be open
(unless there is a compelling reason against this), shareable, open-format, and machine-readable to allow mass
processing (Ubaldi, 2013).
Chapter 5
1.
To take the United Kingdom as an example, “…if development were only about aid, then someone would be
bound to ask whether we need a Cabinet-level minister to manage aid to twenty or thirty mostly small low-
income countries” (Maxwell, 2013).
Annex B
1.
This typology of instruments available to governments follows the seminal classication by Vedung (2007),
which distinguishes among economic means (“carrots”), regulations (“sticks”), and information (“sermons”).
2.
Amid many denitional uncertainties, this paper follows Sturgess (2018) in using “commissioning” to mean the
assessment of a need and the design of a response in addition to its funding.
3.
OECD (1997) gives the example of a health service spending money on outputs that evidence-based medicine
suggests are useless—for example, most tonsillectomies. So even if lots of tonsillectomies are being performed
and we see movement toward the social objective of improved public health, since no causality can be attributed
to the surgeries, the quality of tonsillectomies as an output is zero.
4.
Vedung (2007) addresses the question of what is the difference between a tax (economic policy action) and
a regulation (administered action), since both involve a “measure of authority or obligatory force” (p. 10).
Taking the example of tobacco purchasing, his explanation is that “a prohibition forbids the action proper—
tobacco purchasing—while the obligation…applies to the payment of the tax when you purchase cigars, not the
purchasing itself.” In other words, the economic policy action allows certain behaviors but might make them
more expensive, while the administered action can ban it outright under certain circumstances.
Annex D
1.
Sectors are:
High-level grouping of economic activities based on the on the types of goods and services produced;
Used to indicate which part of the economy is supported by the World Bank intervention; and
Mutually exclusive.
Sectors are not:
Reections of the World Bank’s administrative structure;
Used to indicate methods of delivery of World Bank support or ways of doing business; or
Endnotes
“Advice, Money, Results – Rethinking International Support for Managing Public Finance”
International Working Group Report, New York University
133
Measures of outcomes (such as corporate priorities).
(World Bank, 2016a, p. i).
2.
Themes are:
Goals and objectives of World Bank-supported activities;
Policy areas; and/or
Used to capture World Bank support to the Sustainable Development Goals.
Themes are not:
Methods or instruments of delivery of World Bank support or ways of doing business; or
Mutually exclusive.
(World Bank, 2016b, p. i).
3.
More specically, the themes included in the charts are:
Debt Management and Fiscal Sustainability
Macroeconomic Management
Municipal Finance
Public Expenditure, Financial Management, and Procurement
Tax Policy and Administration
Annex E
1.
ODA refers to nancial ows (both grants and loans) to countries on the DAC list of ODA recipients and
multilateral institutions: (a) that are provided by ofcial agencies, including state and local governments or
by government agencies; and (b) for which each transaction is administered with the promotion of economic
development and welfare as the main objective, is concessional, and conveys a grant element of at least 25
percent (discount rate of 10 percent) (AlphaBeta, 2018, p. 7).
2.
Data prior to 2002 are incomplete and reportedly reect only 70 percent of donors’ ODA reporting.
3.
The Hudson Institute indicates that the total of private ows (US$ 801 billion in 2014) are more than ve times
greater than ofcial ows (US$ 147 billion, including US$ 137 billion from DAC donors and US$ 10 billion from
11 non-DAC donors over the same period). However, these totals hide the obvious point that the majority of these
private ows are comprised of foreign direct investment and remittances. Nevertheless, private philanthropy was
US$ 64.4 billion for that year, of which US$ 63.7 billion was from DAC donors (Hudson Institute, 2016).
Annex I
1.
This is a reference to the consensus that Williamson identied as emerging de facto, with its emphasis on a
paradigmatic shift in favor of macroeconomic stabilization and market-based development—not the more
ideological version that subsequently formed the basis for much controversy (Birdsall, de la Torre & Valencia
Caicedo, 2010).
Annex K
1.
See, for example:
The Elders (https://www.theelders.org/)
“Brain Trust,” such as that of Franklin Roosevelt in the United States in the 1930s (https://www.nytimes.
com/1932/11/20/archives/the-cabinet-mr-roosevelt-already-has-the-group-of-advisers-who.html)
Economic policy “Brain Trust” to Shinzo Abe in Japan in 2012 (Abb, Köllner, and Maslow, 2016).
G20 Eminent Persons Group on Global Financial Governance (https://www.globalnancialgovernance.org/
about-g20-epg/)
Independent Challenge Group for the 2010 Spending Review in the UK (https://webarchive.nationalarchives.
gov.uk/20130102173537/http://www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/spend_icg_members.htm)
“Wise Men” of economic forecasting in 1990s in the United Kingdom (https://www.independent.co.uk/news/uk/
the-not-quite-so-magnicent-seven-the-treasury-plans-to-set-up-a-panel-of-outside-advisers-robert-1563383.
html)
External Advisory Group for the Review of the IMF’s Capacity Development Strategy (https://www.imf.org/~/
media/Files/Publications/PP/2018/pp1002182018reviewfunds-cdstrategyextadvisory.ashx)
134
“Iwakura Mission” by Japan to the United States and Europe in the 1870s (https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
Iwakura_Mission)
“Tswalu Dialogues” on economic development run by the Oppenheimer family and the Brenthurst Foundation
(http://www.thebrenthurstfoundation.org/what-we-do/)
“Balcerowicz Plan” and commission of experts to advise the Polish nance minister in 1989 (https://
en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Balcerowicz_Plan)
2.
See OECD DAC peer reviews of members (http://www.oecd.org/dac/peer-reviews/);
IMF Article IV reviews (https://www.imf.org/external/about/econsurv.htm); and
EC Structural Reform Support Service (https://ec.europa.eu/info/departments/structural-reform-support-service_
en).
3.
Individual examples include Joseph Stiglitz advising the Papandreou government in Greece during the Eurozone
crisis, Jeffrey Sachs advising the Polish government from 1989 during the economic transition, Paul Collier in
Uganda in the 1990s, and Steven Radelet in Liberia in 1990s and 2000s. Independent agencies include AGI/TB-
IGC, CABRI, HKS-BSC, HIID, ODI, IGC, Duke, ACET, NIPFP, ANU-DPC, Fiscus Ltd, and IFS.
4.
Based on the personal experience of one of the principal authors of the present paper, who participated in such an
engagement in China.
5.
For further discussion of the incentives at play in lending operations and provision of policy advice between the
Government of China and the World Bank, as one example of a multilateral development nancing and advisory
organization, see discussion by the panellists at a CGD event in April 2019 (https://www.cgdev.org/event/future-
world-bank-under-next-president).
6.
International Growth Centre research and advice in Ethiopia on economic policy (https://www.theigc.org/impact/
mapping-industrialisation-africa/) and (https://www.theigc.org/publication/an-enterprise-map-of-ethiopia-by-
john-sutton/).
7.
G7 CONNEX Initiative and CONNEX Support Unit (http://connex-unit.org/)
Endnotes